BTS Navigation Bar

NTL Menu


Funding Transportation Needs in the North Central Texas Area



		Funding Transportation
		Needs in the North
		Central Texas Area

January 1987

Click HERE for graphic.

		  FUNDING TRANSPORTATION NEEDS

		IN THE NORTH CENTRAL TEXAS AREA





		   A Report Prepared for

	North Central Texas Council of Governments

		Transportation and Energy Department





		The Center for Applied Research
		School of Social Sciences
		The University of Texas at Dallas
		Richardson, Texas 75083-0688

		     January 18, 1987



[The preparation of this document was financed through a 
grant from and disseminated under the sponsorship of the 
Urban Mass Transportation Administration, U.S. Department       
of Transportation, and the United States Government 
assumes no liability for its contents or use thereof.]


Acknowledgments

In the work leading to this report, useful 
information and suggestions were received from Gordon 
Shunk, Bahar Norris and Paul Waddell of the North Central 
Texas Council of Governments.

The Center for Applied Research in the School of 
Social Sciences at the University of Texas at Dallas 
coordinates the research activities of the School.  This 
report was prepared by Irving Hoch, Kurt Beron, and David 
Merriman (faculty members in Economics); Jay Gilberg and 
Richard Straton (faculty members in Public 
Administration); and William Dixon (UTD Research 
Assistant).


TABLE OF CONTENTS

PART I INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY				 1
	  Study Goals					 1
	  Alternatives to Revenue Increases		 1
	  Relative Levels of Need and Revenue Potential	 4
	  Coverage of Remainder of Report		 6
	  Revenue Implications				10

PART II: DETAILED DISCUSSION OF REVENUE RAISING 
         FINANCIAL DEVICES				17

	  The Financial Devices				17

	I. ROAD USE DIRECT CHARGES			19

	   A. Toll Road Revenue				21
	   B. Electronic Road Pricing			34

	II. JOINT PUBLIC-PRIVATE FINANCING		40

	    A. Development Impact Fees			51
	    B. Benefit Assessment Districts		64
	    C. Leasing or Sale of Development or Air
               Rights					71
	    D. Developer Contributions Through 
               Negotiations				74

	III. PARKING FEES, FINES AND TAXES		77

	 IV. LOCAL OPTION MOTOR FUEL TAXES		82

	 V. LOCAL SALES TAXES				91

	VI. PROPERTY TAXES				100

	VII. VEHICLE LICENSE FEES AND REGISTRATION FEES	117

	VIII. NEW TYPES OF TAXES AND REVENUE SOURCES	122

		A. Payroll Tax				125
		B. Aviation Fuel Tax			128
		C. Lottery				130

	IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES			134

APPENDIX: HIGHWAY FINANCE EXPERIENCE IN CALIFORNIA	147

BIBLIOGRAPHY						162


PART I  INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY


PART I: INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY

Study Goals

The North Central Texas Council of Governments (NCTCOG) 
has estimated that $16.9 billion will be needed to fund 
the transportation developments called for in its 
"Mobility 2000" plan for the Dallas-Fort Worth area, but 
given the current tax and revenue structure, government 
agencies serving the NCTCOG area will have only $10.5 
billion available for those facilities. Thus, a gap of 
some $6.4 billion occurs between discerned requirements 
and expected revenues.1   This study has the goal of 
developing information of help in closing that gap.  
Obviously, the gap can be closed either by increasing 
transportation revenues, directly or indirectly, or by 
decreasing requirements.  The bulk of the effort of this 
study is directed to the first option, that of direct 
increases in revenue.  This includes both increasing 
revenue from current sources and tapping new sources of 
revenue through a number of innovative devices.  The 
alternatives to direct revenue increases are worth at 
least some attention, however.

Alternatives to Revenue Increases

The major indirect source of increased revenue is that of 
increased economic growth, generating more income than 
currently anticipated and consequently, more government 
revenue than currently projected.  Transportation 
investment can be viewed as one of a number of 
instruments to promote economic growth, and investment 
decisions can be based explicitly on that criterion. 
Forkenbrock and Plazak2 note that 36 states explicitly 
take economic development into account in their highway 
programming activities, and report on those programs in 
some detail.  Viewed across all states, the level of 
effort currently seems relatively modest.  Of the 36 
states with economic development programs, 15 simply 
incorporate development objectives within their highway 
programming


-2-
process.  A few states, however, do have significant 
levels of funding for the activity, with four states 
spending roughly $10 million a year and Iowa spending 
close to $30 million a year on economic development 
through highway programs.  Iowa's funds are obtained from 
a 2-cent motor fuel tax with proceeds dedicated to 
economic development.  Eleven states have programs 
primarily directed to making industrial parks more 
accessible, supplementing local ant private funds in 
financing interchanges, frontage roads or other access 
roads.  Matching funds are usually a condition for state 
contributions.  Eight states have quick-response 
capabilities, used to expedite construction, for example 
by speeding review procedures and by making capital 
readily available.  States operating under each of the 
program types are identified in Table 1.

Reduction in requirements can occur indirectly, through 
the involuntary and painful effect of an unanticipated 
slowdown in economic growth.  It can also occur through 
the exercise of policy options aimed at limiting the 
growth of highway traffic, including use of both 
non-price incentives and pricing. Natalie McConnell-Fay 
notes a number of non-price incentives currently employed 
in the San Francisco Bay Area to reduce traffic.3   The 
Metropolitan Transportation Commission, the regional 
planning organization for Bay Area transportation, has 
introduced a Traffic Mitigation Program which helps 
support such activities as the work of traffic 
coordinators at 300 large corporations, shuttles to rapid 
transit stations, subsidies for transit use, and car 
pooling.  The traffic coordinators help business 
employees find alternatives to commuting to work in 
private cars.  Those programs in effect involve subsidies 
to reduce private vehicle use.  Alternatively, the direct 
charging of fees for road use can also be considered as a 
congestion reduction device.  A recent special issue of 
Transportation Research 4 contains a number of papers on 
the implementation of such fees. The focus there is on 
the reduction of congestion, but such fees


-3-



Notes:
a "Economic Development Objectives in 
   Programming" means that the state specifically takes 
   economic development into account in its capital 
   programming process or has special highway programs to 
   encourage economic development.
b "Special Economic Development Funds/Bonding" means 
   that the state has a categorical funding source or 
   bonding authority for economic development or industrial 
   park roads.
c "Industrial Park Program" means that the state has a 
  special program dedicated to constructing this type of 
  road.
d"Quick-Response Capabilities" means that the state has 
  the ability to expedite economic development-related road 
  projects.
e Expedites environmental review for economic 
  development projects. 
f Proposed "AHEAD" program, which has not yet passed in 
  the state legislature.

Source: Reproduced from Table 1 in David J. Forkenbrock 
        and David J. Plazak "Economic Development and State 
        Level Transportation Policy"  Transportation Quarterly,
        Vol. 40, No. 2, April, 1986, pp. 148-149.


-4-
also can be important sources of revenue, of primary 
interest here.  In particular, one of the devices 
considered is an electronic sensing mechanism that 
measures road use in particular areas, successfully 
employed on an experimental basis in Hong Kong.  The 
discussion of that device will be drawn on later in this 
report, emphasizing its innovative application in raising 
revenue.

Relative Levels of "Need" and Revenue Potential 

Although the six-billion dollar shortfall for the 
implementation of "Mobility 2000" obviously is a 
considerable sum, it can be argued that there are some 
mitigating features in the burden posed by that 
shortfall.  First, many other states have considerably 
greater ratios of planned expenditures (or "needs") to 
expected revenues, so their relative funding gaps are 
greater than those of Texas.  Second, local rates of 
taxation appear relatively low, compared to other 
jurisdictions of comparable population size.  Of course, 
it is politically unpalatable to suggest increasing 
taxes; nevertheless, it seems worth noting that local tax 
rates currently are not "excessive", in relative terms.  
In turn, this suggests there is considerable potential 
for reducing or closing the "Mobility 2000" revenue gap.  
The evidence for these arguments is as follows.

On the first point, evidence presented by Peter L. Shaw,5 
reproduced here as Table 2, is pertinent.  In a 
Congressional study, Texas' highway requirements from 
1983 to 2000 were listed as $58.4 billion, contrasted 
with projected highway revenues of $52.7 billion.  (The 
shortfall here, for the state as a whole, is less than 
that for the NCTCOG planning area, presumably because of 
lower projected needs or higher projected revenues in 
these figures than in those of "Mobility 2000".)  The 
Texas ratio of needs to revenue is 58.4/52.7 or 1.11.  
For the U.S. as a whole, the ratio is 720,230/455,334 or 
1.58.


-5-
			TABLE 2
PROJECTED CAPITAL NEEDS, REVENUE, AND REVENUE
SHORTFALL FOR CASE-STUDY STATES AND THE UNITED STATES,
			BY FUNCTION


Click HERE for graphic.

Source: Reproduced from Table IV in Peter L. Shaw, "The 
Surface Transportation Assistance Act of 1982: Short-term 
Hopes ant Long Term Implications", Transportation 
Quarterly, July, 1986, pp. 426-427. Originally appearing 
in U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, Hard Choices, 
A Report on the Increasing Gap Between America's 
Infrastructure Needs and Our Ability to Pay for Them, 
Washington, D. C., 98th Congress, 2nd Season, Senate 
Print, 98-164, February 25, 1984, p. 57.


-6-
Evidence on the second point is furnished by research 
carried out by F. Jay Cummings.6  Cummings concludes that 
total state and local tax bills for the residents of 
Dallas, Houston and San Antonio are usually lower than 
those for other cities.  Specific evidence that he 
presents, reproduced here as Table 3, shows that state 
and local tax bills for the residents of Dallas are 
generally the lowest of all 30 cities that he 
investigated.  His data refer to tax rates as of 1978 and 
to city rather than metropolitan area taxes.  However, 
more recent data show that Houston's state and local 
taxes per capita as of 1981 remained low relative to 
those of most large cities,7 and presumably the Dallas 
experience parallels that of Houston.  It also seems 
plausible that taxes for metropolitan areas as a whole 
parallel those of their major central cities.  No doubt, 
the absence of state income taxes is a major factor in 
the relatively low overall state and local tax burden for 
the residents of Texas.  The relatively low burden likely 
still holds despite recent "temporary" increases in state 
sales and gasoline taxes for much of 1987.8

Coverage of Remainder of Report 
Following this introductory section, Part II develops 
information on financial devices that can be used to 
raise needed highway revenue, and projects expected 
revenue that can be obtained under each device.  Because 
California is a trend-setting state, considerable 
attention is devoted to its current experience in highway 
finance and policy, with results drawn on both in Part II 
and in an appendix to this report.  A bibliography 
concludes the report.

The projections of Part II, of course, are estimates, and 
in some cases, relatively crude estimates; nevertheless, 
they should be useful in gauging potential sources of 
revenue to help close the "Mobility 2000" funding gap. 
The development of the projections is documented in some 
detail, and should point the way to more refined 
estimates, as needed.


-7-

Click HERE for graphic.

-8-
The coverage of the financial devices can be outlined as 
 follows:

   I. Road Use Direct Charges
      A. Toll Road Revenue
      B. Electronic Road Pricing

  II. Joint Public-Private Financing
      A. Development Impact Fees
      B. Benefit Assessment Districts
      C. Leasing or Sale of Development Rights or Air Rights
      D. Developer Contributions Through Negotiations

 III. Parking Fees, Fines and Taxes
  IV. Local Option Motor Fuel Taxes V. Local Sales Taxes
  VI. Property Taxes
 VII. Vehicle Registration Fees
VIII. New Types of Taxes and Revenue Sources
      A. Payroll tax
      B. Aviation fuel tax
      C. Lottery
  IX. Borrowing Strategies

The organization of these categories represents a 
blending of several criteria, including directness of 
charges, likely feasibility and degree of innovation.  
Thus, the direct beneficiaries of highway improvements 
are highway users, with toll road pricing involving the 
most direct charge for use, followed by gasoline taxes, 
parking fees and fines, and registration fees for 
vehicles.  But an improved highway system also implies 
benefits for developers and land owners whose land is on 
or near highways, yielding the rationale for such items 
as benefit assessment districts and expanded property 
taxes.  Finally, all residents of a region with improved 
access share in the benefits of that improvement, making 
the case for the use of the sales tax, a payroll tax and 
a lottery as a source of revenue for highways.


-9-
A variety of political and administrative considerations 
affect the likely feasibility of various financing 
mechanisms.  Certainly, borrowing strategies, which take 
advantage of institutional rules to maximize revenue, 
will be widely acceptable, since no taxation is involved 
in their use.  Costs that fall on non-local residents, 
such as tolls on toll roads serving interstate traffic, 
will be popular.  "Indirect" charges that are a component 
of a much larger cost item, such as impact fees, gasoline 
taxes and sales taxes, will have appeal, politically.  
Property taxes, on the other hand, because of their high 
visibility and discreteness of collection, are likely to 
be resisted.

Finally, a major criterion guiding the efforts of this 
project was the investigation of relatively new methods 
of highway finance, accounting for the prominence given 
to toll roads, particularly electronic road pricing, and 
to charges based on the costs of increased traffic 
generation or to the capturing of some gains in land 
values due to new highways.

In the body of this report, each of the financial 
mechanisms in the outline above will be covered, in turn.  
Coverage will consist of an overview of the device; when 
appropriate, additional discussion of the device, 
including both general information and case studies; 
revenue implications of the device for NCTCOG area 
highway construction; and a list of citations documenting 
information sources.

Each overview covers the following topics: definition of 
the device; examples of its use; information on financial 
results of its use; and major issues involved in its use, 
including legal-administrative, political and economic 
issues.


-10-
Revenue Implications
Table 4 summarizes the key results of this study by exhibiting 
the revenueimplications of each financial device, described in 
detail in the main body of this report.  A number of items 
should be noted here, however, to clarify the entries in Table
 4:

(1) The geographic coverage aimed at in each case is that of
    the NCTCOG transportation planning area, which includes 
    all of Dallas and Tarrant Counties, most of Collin and 
    Denton Counties, and small sections of the other counties 
    to the east and south of Dallas County, and to the west and
    south of Tarrant County.9   For some of the financial 
    devices, because of data constraints, the geographic area 
    referenced consists only of the four counties: Collin, 
    Dallas, Denton, and Tarrant; however the geographic and 
    economic coverage of those counties corresponds quite 
    closely to the NCTCOG planning area.

(2) Revenue figures are in "real" dollars as of the current 
    price level, so they are directly comparable.  No 
    adjustment for inflation is necessary.

(3) The projection period is from 1986 to the year 2010, 
    a total of 24 years.  In effect, this allows an additional 
    10 years to implement the goals of "Mobility 2000".10

(4) In obtaining each projection, the current level of annual 
    revenue was estimated, and then current increments to that 
    level were inferred under various scenarios.  In turn, each
    current increment was multiplied by 24, the span of years 
    from 1986 to 2010, to yield a "low" estimate -- the 
    "Minimum Growth" case of Table 4.  The "high" estimate, or
    the "Normal Growth" case of Table 4, was then obtained by 
    multiplying the "low" figure by 1.5, to yield 36 times the 
    annual figure.  The estimate for 1.5 is based on a 
    projection of growth in real income for the Dallas-Fort 
    Worth metroplex from 1986 to 2010, which essentially 
    involves a doubling of income.  (To be precise, Year 2010 
    income/Year 1986 income equals 2.13.)11    An "average" 
    figure for the period is then a "halfway" figure, or 1.5, 
    setting the base year value at 1.0 and the terminal year 
    value at 2.0, and assuming linear growth.  Hence, 
    accounting for "normal growth" in income, and in income 
    related measures, is obtained by scaling base year entries 
    by 1.5.

(5) In comparing low and high projections, note that 
    multiplication of the "current level" annual figure by 24 
    yields a projection that assumes the current level of 
    revenue is unchanged.  The result furnishes a useful 
    benchmark.  But in some cases, the current level is based 
    on a total, and in some cases, the current-level is based 
    on an increment accounting for an annual change or amount 
    of growth.  The two sets of numbers are fully consistent 
    only if there is a proper accounting for growth, as occurs 
    in the "high" projections, which can be viewed as the


-11-
			     TABLE 4
		   SUMMARY OF REVENUE ESTIMATES

		             Estimated Total Revenue Increment
		            1986-2110 in Millions of Dollars*

Source of Revenue              "Minimum Growth" "Normal Growth" 
                                  Case (low)      Case (high)                 

I.  ROAD USE DIRECT CHARGES
   
    A. Toll Road Revenue

       Increased tolls, per mile 
         of new tollway              31                47
         per 50 miles of new 
         tollway                    1560             2340
      Increase current toll from 
         5˘ to 10˘ per mile of 
         existing tollway             49               74

    B. Electronic Road Pricing

       1˘ per vehicle mile of 
         travel (VMT) on freeways   2880             4320
       1˘ per VMT of peakload on 
         freeways                   1152             1728

II.   JOINT PUBLIC-PRIVATE FINANCING
      Charging For Costs of 
      Increased Traffic and/or 
      Capturing Some of Land 
      Value Appreciation
      from New Highways

      A. Development Impact Fees
         Residential, $100 per Unit  177              265
         Office, $1 per square foot  312              468
         Retail, Commercial $1 
          per sq ft.                 240              360
         Industrial, 20˘ per square 
            foot                      72              108
                                     801             1201
      B. Benefit Assessment Districts
         Limited to Dallas  CBD      204              306
         Other areas                 276              414
                                     480              720

      C. Leasing or Sale of 
         Development Rights or Air 
         Rights                      500              750

      D. Developer Contributions 
         Through Negotiations
         Transportation corpo-
         rations, ad hoc
         negotiations, contributed 
         right of way, and 
         infrastructure              500             750

     Totals: There is overlap in 
     the coverage of these cases, 
     so if all were implemented,
     the totals would be lower, 
     probably:                      1500            2250

     Additional Note: Relatively 
     low fees and rates were 
     employed in above estimates.  
     It would be possible to 
     consider doubling those fees 
     and rates to yield:            3000           4500


*Note: These are selected from a wider range of estimates 
presented in the body of this report, with the 
aim of "reasonableness" of estimates.


-12-
		TABLE 4 ( continued)

		SUMMARY OF REVENUE ESTIMATES

			     Estimated Total Revenue Increment
                            1986 -2010 in Millions of  Dollars

 Source of Revenue            "Minimum Growth"  "Normal Growth"
                                 Case (low)        Case (high)

III. PARKING FEES, FINE AND TAXES

     A. Minimum Estimate -moderate
        expansion  of metering  in 
        Dallas,                         12              18
        none in Fort Worth

     B. Maximum Estimate               600             900

IV.  LOCAL OPTION MOTOR FUEL TAX   
   
     A.  Local Excise Tax
         1˘  per gallon                480             720
         1˘  per gallon                960            1440
 
     B.  Local Sales Tax on Motor Fuel               
         1% tax                        360             540

V.   LOCAL SALES TAX

     A. Share of DART 1% Sales Tax
        one-twentieth share highways   186             281
     
     B. General Sales Tax  (local 1% 
        rate)
        add 0.25% for highways        1710            2526

     C. Expand Sales Subject to Sales 
        Tax from 30%          
        to 100%, on additional 70% 
        subject to tax   
        apply 0.10% to highways       1620            2430
        apply 0.25% to highways       4050            6075

VI. PROPERTY TAXES

    A. Increase County Property Taxes 
       by 5%                           192             288
    
    B. Bring County Road and Bridge 
       Property Tax to State Average   194             292
 
    C. Appraise and Tax Motor Vehicles 
       in County Property Tax, 
       appraised value per 
       Vehicle - 1736                 158              237

    D. Increase City Property Taxes 
       by 5%                          633              950


-13-

			TABLE 4 (continued)

			SUMMARY OF REVENUE ESTIMATES

			     Estimated Total Revenue Increment
			    1986-2010 in Millions of Dollars

Source of Revenue             "Minimum Growth" "Normal Growth"
                                  Case (low)     Case (high)

VII. VEHICLE REGISTRATION FEES

     A. General Registration:
        Payments to Counties in 
        proportion to payments 
        paid                           437           655
 
     B. County Road and Bridge Fee:
        Increase registration fee 
        from  $5 to $10                350           525

VIII. NEW TYPES OF TAXES AND REVENUE 
      SOURCES
  
     A. Payroll Tax
        0.1% tax on payrolls          720          1080
        0.1% tax on payrolls         2160          3240

    B. Aviation Fuel Tax    
       1˘  per gallon                 168           252
       1˘ per gallon                  336           504

    C. Lottery - (All net proceeds
       to highways)                   890          1335

IX.  BORROWING STRATEGIES
       
       Arbitrage Under New Federal 
       Tax Law                         60            60*
       Arbitrage Based on Return to 
       Earlier (in force as of 1986) 
       Legal Provisions               240           240*



* Based on $6 billion NCTCOG revenue gap; hence, high and 
  low values here are the same.


-14-

    result of "normal" growth.  To expand on the point: 
    sales tax revenue is based on current total sales, 
    which if unchanged, imply zero growth in the 
    Dallas-Fort Worth economy.  In contrast, impact fee 
    estimates assume impact fees are imposed on new 
    construction, which in turn implies that recent 
    growth rates continue unchanged.

(6) The timing of revenues collected has not been 
    addressed beyond the implicit assumption that current 
    annual revenues continue at the same rate, or 
    alternatively, increase in linear fashion.  However, if 
    revenue collection is subject to time differences, interest
    rates and discounting come into play: a dollar today is 
    worth more than a dollar tomorrow, and the difference 
    depends on the interest rate.  Revenues collected early 
    are worth more than revenues collected late.  Hence, the 
    flow of revenues can greatly affect the real level of 
    total revenues collected.  This issue is addressed in this 
    report, in part, by the consideration of borrowing 
    strategies at the conclusion of the report.  However, 
    additional work addressing this issue would be worthwhile.

(7) In Table 4, there is overlap in some of the cases 
    (in particular, see the figures on joint public-private 
    financing).  Of more importance, it is hardly likely that 
    all, or even a large number of the scenarios will be 
    implemented jointly.  However, the results do suggest that 
    a judicious mix of several of the financial devices should
    yield enough returns to close the revenue gap.  In 
    particular, some sense of the magnitude of prospective 
    revenue under each of the projections can be obtained by 
    selecting a "most reasonable" revenue scenario for each 
    financial device and then obtaining the revenue total.  
    Admitting the relative arbitrariness of the approach, the 
    enumeration on the next page exemplifies the results that 
    can be obtained in this manner.   The scenario employed for
    each case is shown in brief fashion.  From the enumeration 
    it can be seen that the combination of scenarios selected, 
    even for the low (or minimum growth) case, yields revenues 
    above the $6.4 billion needed to close the "Mobility 
    2000" revenue gap.

	Part II of this report, which follows the present 
introductory section, consists of a detailed discussion 
of the financial devices, covering each in turn.


-15-

   Source of Revenue		Scenario           Revenue in
   (Financial Device)	                       Million Dollars
		                                Low       High

I. Road Use Direct Charges    25 miles of new 
                                 tollway         780     1170

II. Joint Public-Private     Use all options
	Financing           recognizing overlap 1500     2250

III. Parking Fees,	    Half of maximum
     Fines and Taxes	    estimate (III B)     300      450

IV. Local Option	    Local fuel tax at 
    Motor Fuel Taxes	    1˘ per gallon        480     720

V. Local Sales Taxes	    Add 0.125% for       
                            highways             855	1283

VI. Property Taxes	    Use all options      1177	1767

VII. Vehicle Registration   Fees Use all options  787	1180

VIII. New Types of Taxes    Aviation fuel tax
      and Revenue Sources   at 1˘ per gal.        168	 252
			    Lottery - half of
                            proceeds              445    668

IX. Borrowing Strategies    New federal tax law 
                            (low), partial return 
                            to old law (high)     60     120
	       Total	                         6552    9860


-16-

		Notes to Introduction and Summary

1. North Central Texas Council of Governments, Mobility 
   2000: The Regional Transportation Plan for North Central 
   Texas, Arlington, Texas, May,  1986, 7.

2. David J. Forkenbrock and David J. Plazak," Economic 
   Development and State-Level Transportation Policy", 
   Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40, No. 2, April, 1986, 
   143-157.  Also see David J. Forkenbrock, "Highway Revenues 
   and Expenditures: Some Emerging Policy Directions at the 
   State Level", in Lester A. Hoel, Editor, Innovative 
   Financing For Transportation: Practical Solutions and 
   Experiences, Office of the Secretary of Transportation, U.S.
   Department of Transportation, Washington, D. C., April, 
   1986. (DOT-1-86-20).

3. Natalie McConnell-Fay "Tackling Traffic Congestion in 
   the San Francisco Bay Area", Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 
   40, No. 2, April, 1986, 159-170.

4. Transportation Research - A, General, Vol. 20A, No. 2, 
   March 1986, Special Issue Devoted to Road Pricing.

5. Peter L. Shaw, "The Surface Transportation Assistance 
   Act of 1982: Short-term Hopes and Long Term Implications," 
   Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40, No. 3, July 1986, 
   411-432.

6. F. Jay Cummings, "State and Local Tax Bills: How Do 
   Residents of Large Cities Fare?" Texas Business Review, Vol.
   56, No. 1, Jan., 1982, 34-39.

7. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the 
   United States, 1984 edition, Table 485, "Estimated State and
   Local Taxes Paid by a Family of Four in Selected Large 
   Cities, by Income Level: 1981," p. 302.

8. In 1986, in response to fiscal concerns, the Texas 
   Legislature increased state sales taxes from 4.15 to 5.25 
   cents per dollar of taxable sales, and gasoline taxes from 
   10˘ to 150 per gallon, for the period Jan. 1 to  Aug. 31, 
   1987.  Many observers expect these increases to be extended 
   beyond August 31, 1987, with increases in other taxes 
   possible.  It nevertheless seems plausible that total state 
   and local taxes will remain below levels elsewhere, given an
   apparent reluctance to institutestate income taxes.

9. The NCTCOG transportation planning area is shown in a 
   map appearing in North Central Texas Council of Government, 
   Mobility 2000; that planning area is essentially the same as
   the NCTCOG policy planning area, with the later area shown 
   in North Central Texas Council of Governments, Population 
   and Employment Projections by City, June 1984.

10. This assumption was suggested by NCTCOG.

11. Data Resources, Incorporated (DRI), Forecast of Revenues 
    from the Dallas Area Rapid Transit Tax: State and Local 
    Government Practice, May 1986, Tables 3 and 4.  Some 
    caution must be employed in using the DRI data, because 
    many of their series build in a projection of inflation. 
    Thus, for the year 2010, "nominal" income is projected as 
    7.235 the 1986 level, with 3.405 accounting for inflation, 
    and 2.125 for growth in real income 
    (2.125 x 3.405 = 7.235).


PART II DETAILED DISCUSSION OF REVENUE RAISING FINANCIAL 
DEVICES


-17-

PART II: DETAILED DISCUSSION OF REVENUE RAISING FINANCIAL 
DEVICES

The Financial Devices

This part of the report discusses the financial devices 
that can be used to increase highway revenues, covering 
each device in turn.  There are nine
sections:
  I. Road Use Direct Charges
  II. Joint Public-Private Financing
 III. Parking Fees, Fines and Taxes
  IV. Local Option Motor Fuel Taxes
   V. Local Sales Taxes
  VI. Property Taxes
 VII. Vehicle Registration Fees
VIII. New Types of Taxes and Revenue Sources
  IX. Borrowing Strategies

Each section begins with a one page overview or set of 
one page overviews describing each device or set of 
mechanisms subcategorized under each device.  The 
overviews appear in distinctive single space format to 
set them off from the rest of the text.  Each overview 
contains a definition of the device, examples of its use, 
information on the financial results of its use, and 
major issues involved in its use, including 
legal-administrative, political and economic issues.  The 
overviews are followed by detailed discussions which 
contain general or background information, case studies, 
revenue implications, and a list of sources drawn upon in 
the discussion.

The "revenue implications" subsections exhibit estimates 
for current revenue, if any, that the device contributes 
for highway use in the NCTCOG planning


-18-

area, and potential current revenue on an annual basis.  
Then low and high estimates are obtained for total 
revenue over the period 1986-2010 by respectively 
multiplying current annual revenue by 24 and 36; the 
rationale for these multiplications is developed above in 
Part I.  Table 4 of Part I summarizes the revenue 
increments achievable by employing each device, and is 
useful for comparative purposes.  As noted on the basis 
of that table, and as developed in detail in this part of 
the report, the potential for closing the "Mobility 2000" 
revenue gap does indeed exist.


-19-

			I. ROAD USE DIRECT CHARGES
			I.A   TOLL ROAD REVENUE
				Overview

Definition

The use of revenues from the sale of bonds backed by 
tolls collected from the users of roads, tunnels and 
bridges to pay for these facilities.  The toll revenues 
may be supplemented by public funds.

Examples

Dallas North Tollway, Dallas, TX
Richmond Expressway System, Richmond, VA
South Crosstown Expressway, Tampa, FL

Financial Results

The range of toll revenues for the examples above in 1984 
varied from $5.6 to $20.7 million annually.  Supplemental 
receipts from bond sales, investments, rentals and 
concessions, and miscellaneous bring the total revenues 
into the range of $13.6 to $32.3 million annually.

Passenger car rates per mile on rural toll roads 
typically are on the order of 2 cents per mile; urban 
toll roads often charge considerably more, ranging from 5 
to 10 cents per mile.  Generally, toll roads are 
considered to be substantial revenue producers.  Overhead 
usually is low.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative The establishment of a governing 
  authority requires state-enabling legislation, but once 
  in place, administration is generally efficient due to 
  the authority's independent status.  However, it is 
  difficult in urban areas to control toll facilities that 
  have access every mile or so.

  Political Public acceptance is necessary for toll road 
  use and such roads must serve high demand corridors and 
  provide a faster and/or more convenient alternative to a 
  free facility.

  Toll road development, moreover, generally requires 
  detailed advance planning and avoidance of competition 
  with existing highway systems.  Since most urban areas 
  already have existing facilities, this often precludes a 
  toll road.

  Economic Toll road financing can be viewed as an 
  efficient and equitable financial technique because it is 
  a user fee that charges the direct beneficiaries for 
  their use of the facilities, and it charges similar 
  vehicles an identical charge.


-20-
			I.B ELECTRONIC ROAD PRICING
				Overview

Definition

Computerization and improved methods of communication 
make possible the electronic collection of toll 
information, with billing of road users at the end of a 
payment period (usually a month), in the same fashion as 
credit card billing.

Examples
1) Coronado Bridge "Automatic Vehicle Identification" 
   (AVI)  Experimental System, California

2) Pilot study in Hong Kong, 1983-85

Financial Results

1) The Coronado Bridge system is an experimental project 
of the California State Department of Transportation.  
Bridge crossings are recorded electronically and vehicle 
owners are later billed for total crossings in a given 
period.  Potential savings are 10% of toll collection 
costs by way of replacement of toll collectors, and 
considerable reduction in congestion because of minimal 
delay in passing through the toll collection point.

2) In the Hong Kong Pilot Study, there were a total of 
200 zones, with vehicles charged electronically every 
time they crossed a zone boundary line.  Tolls charged 
per zone ranged from 10˘ to $1.50 (U.S. dollars); 
presumably, a typical trip involved crossing only a few 
zone boundaries. Results were deemed very successful, 
both in terms of reducing traffic congestion and raising 
revenue.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative In the Coronado Bridge case, 
  there have been some technical problems in fitting 
  cars with electronic sensors.  Billing also poses 
  questions.  Charges could be collected through 
  credit cards, or if that fails, through adding 
  costs to vehicle registration fees.

  Political Privacy is an issue, given the collection 
  of data on vehicle movements, particularly in the 
  Hong Kong type of system.  However, there was 
  sensitivity to that issue in the Hong Kong 
  experiment; for example, information listed on 
  bills was limited if vehicle owners so requested. 

  Economic Toll authorities around the world have 
  been investigating the potential for electronic 
  billing for some time.  Major use of the system 
  seems likely soon.  Hong Kong is likely to 
  introduce a permanent system by the end of the 
  decade.  The Hong Kong system makes use of small, 
  inexpensive, robust solid state sensors attached to 
  cars, and inexpensive microcomputers to carry out 
  the billing.


-21-
			IA. TOLL ROAD REVENUE
				Detail

General Information 

Since 1916, the federal government with few exceptions 
has prohibited the levying of tolls on roads built with 
federal aid.  Most of the 5,000 miles of toll roads, 
therefore have been funded through tax-exempt borrowing 
in the bond market.

It has been estimated that the collection of tolls costs 
on average 14 percent of revenues versus collection costs 
of 7 percent for highway user taxes for the average 
state.  Additionally, capital costs can be raised 5 to 30 
percent by having to finance debt through the municipal 
bond market.

Offsetting these costs are the benefits of (1) earlier 
construction of needed highways that otherwise would be 
delayed due to budget constraints and (2) a fairly 
certain revenue stream to maintain the roads.  Despite 
these benefits, the Congressional Budget Office estimates 
that less than 10 percent of existing urban interstate 
highways could financially support a tollway, and this is 
considered an indicator of limited potential for new toll 
roads.  Nevertheless, a number of toll roads, including 
the Dallas North Tollway, are currently financially 
successful.

C. Kenneth Orski argues that after years of languishing 
in semi-obscurity, toll roads are re-emerging as a 
serious fiscal alternative, even though modern toll roads 
require volumes of 50,000 vehicles per day.  Such volumes 
now seem attainable on busy commuter highways.  Thus, the 
Dulles Toll Road, paralleling the Dulles Airport access 
road in suburban Washington, D. C., had a daily volume of 
60,000 vehicles within six months after opening. Further, 
most planned new


-22-

toll roads are commuter highways, including the Hardy 
Toll Road in Houston, the Jacksonville Expressway, the 
North Atlanta Toll Road and the Dallas North Tollway 
extension.

There are two proposed revisions of federal law that 
might make toll roads financially more viable.  H. R. 
4144, legislation submitted by the Reagan Administration, 
contains a provision that would allow federal funds to be 
used for new toll roads or for reconstructing existing 
toll roads.  Federal financial participation of up to 90 
percent would be allowed as per current law.  Previously 
existing non-toll roads would not be eligible. 
Additionally, the bill would allow collection of tolls 
after all nonfederal obligations have been paid, subject 
to the revenue being used for toll road maintenance or 
other public highway construction projects.

More expansive legislation recently introduced would 
allow federal aid to be used both for new toll roads and 
existing roads constructed with federal aid.  H. R. 3473 
and S. 1488 allow toll revenues to be used after 
repayment of debt obligations for highway construction or 
for mass transit or bridges. Unlike the administration 
bill, however, federal financial participation would be 
limited to 50 percent of project costs.

Table 5 lists information on current U.S. toll roads by 
location, length in miles, average toll rate per mile for 
passenger cars, and number of vehicle miles as of 1983.

Case Example - Illinois

The Illinois toll highway system is made up of three toll 
roads consisting of 256 miles of roadway, excluding a 
toll road that Chicago operates separately.  A new 17.5 
mile toll road is scheduled for construction beginning in 
1986 with its opening planned for 1988 or 1989.


-23-

				TABLE 5

			U.S. TOLL ROAD INFORMATION
               
                                        Passenger
					Car 
					Average    Vehicle
 				Length  Rate Per   Miles in
State and Toll                   in     Mile       Millions As                     
Facilities                      Miles   in Cents   of 1983

Connecticut
  Connecticut Turnpike          129.0	    2.2	  2.018.9
  Merrit Parkway                 37.0       0.9     810.2
  Wilbur Cross Parkway           26.6       1.3   

Delaware
  Delaware Turnpike-             11.2       6.7     155.4
  JFK  Memorial Highway

Florida
  Airport Expressway              4.4       5.7      ---
  Beeline Expressway             17.4       2.9      ---
  Beline East                    15.0       1.3      ---
  Beeline West                    9.0       2.2      ---
  Bucaneer Trail                 15.0       9.4      ---
  East-West Expressway            2.0      12.5      ---
  Everglades Parkway             78.0       1.0      ---
  Florida’s Turnpike            265.0       2.4    1,763.6
  Holland East-West              13.8       1.8      ---
  South Dade                      8.0       1.3      ---
  West Dade Expressway           50.0       1.8      ---
  Tempa South Crosstown           9.3       5.4      ---

Illinois
  Tri-State Tollway              77.0       3.1    
  Northwest Tollway              76.0       2.6    3,384.9
  East-West Tollway              96.0       2.8
 
Indiana
  Indiana Toll Toad             156.9       3.0      776.9
  
Kansas
  Kansas Turnkpike              236.0       2.8      592.4


-24-

			TABLE 5 (continued)

		U.S. TOLL ROAD INFORMATION


                                        Passenger
					Car 
					Average    Vehicle
 				Length  Rate Per   Miles in
State and Toll                   in     Mile       Millions As                     
Facilities                      Miles   in Cents   of 1983

Kentucky
  Audubon Parkway                23.4     2.1         26.4
  Blue Grass Parkway             72.1     1.8        119.7
  Cumberland Parkway             88.5     2.3         62.2
  Daniel Boone Parkway           62.7     2.2         70.7
  Green River Parkway            70.2     2.1         69.7
  Jackson Purchase Parkway       52.6     1.7         42.5
  Mountain Parkway               ---      ---        123.1
  Pennyrile Parkway              59.0     1.7        104.9
  Western Ky. Parkway           137.0     1.6        182.9

Maine
  Maine Turnpike                106.0     2.5        537.1

Maryland
  JFK Memorial Highway           43.0     2.3        647.4

Massachusetts
  Mass. Turnpike                123.0     2.9      1,630.9      
  Boston Extension               12.0     6.3        ---

New Jersey
  Atlantic City Expressway       44.0     2.3        528.0
  Garden State Parkway          173.0     1.6      3,855.1
  New Jersey Turnpike           118.0     2.3      3,205.5

New York 
  Thruway  
    Berkshire Section            24.0     2.1        
    Erie Section                 70.0     2.4      4,658.2
    Main Line Section           465.0     2.0 

Ohio
  Ohio Turnpike                 241.2     2.0      1,648.0

Oklahoma
  Cimarron Turnpike              67.7     2.1
  Indian Nation Turnpike        105.2     2.4
  Muskogee Turnpike              53.1     2.4     1,212.0
  Turner Turnpike                86.0     2.3
  Will Rogers Turnpike           88.5     2.3


-25-

			TABLE 5 (continued)

		   U.S. TOLL ROAD INFORMATION


                                        Passenger
					Car 
					Average    Vehicle
 				Length  Rate Per   Miles in
State and Toll                   in     Mile       Millions As                     
Facilities                      Miles   in Cents   of 1983

Miles

Pennsylvania
  Pennsylvania Turnpike        470.0      2.3       3,136.1

Texas
  Dallas North Tollway          10.0      5.0         194.5

West Virginia
  West Virginia Turnpike        88.0      4.3         299.7

Ohters

New Hampshire
  Blue Star I-95 Turnpike       ---      ---         245.1
  F.E. Everett Turnpike         ---      ---         414.2
  Spaulding Turnpike            ---      ---         116.6

Virginia
  Richmond Expressway           ---      ---          92.7
  Richmond-Petersburgh Tpk.     ---      ---         676.6
  Va. Beach-Norfolk Expwy.      ---      ---         405.8
  Dulles Toll Road              ---      7.0          ---


--- Information not readily available.

Sources:
International Bridge, Tunnel and Turnpike Association 
      (IBTTA), Toll Rates Survey: U.S. & Canada Roads, 
      Washington, D.C., July 1985, and IBTTA, Turnpike Accident
      and Fatality Report, 1982-1983, Washington, D.C. April 
      17, 1984.

U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Toll Financing of U.S. 
     Highways; Washington, D.C., October 1985, p. 46.


-26-

The Illinois toll road system is operated by a single 
agency, the Illinois State Toll Highway Authority, which 
is independent of both the federal and state departments 
of transportation.  The Authority is fully mandated to 
build and operate toll highways in the state, including 
the power to issue and sell bonds to finance all costs 
associated with the toll highways.  All bonds must be 
backed solely by projected toll revenue with no support 
by the state or any locality.  (This is also the 
situation in Texas with the Texas Turnpike Authority).  
At the end of 1984, the Authority had issued $628,450,000 
in bonds since 1955 of which $364,999,000 had been 
retired. Revenue information for calendar year 1984 
includes the following:

	Toll revenues                              $157,327,494
	Revenues from concessions, interest,
	overweight tickets, miscellaneous             4,780,891
	Total operating revenues                    162,108,385
	Total maintenance and operating expenditures 56,639,136
	Net operating revenues                      105,469,249

The net operating revenues are required by the bond 
resolution to be dedicated to five different accounts 
which are, in order of priority: Maintenance and 
operating, interest, interest reserve, sinking fund, and 
general reserve.

The general reserve fund is used to maintain and 
rehabilitate toll roads and accounted for $58 million in 
expenditures in 1984.  The Authority chooses  
construction companies through an open bidding system.  
Cost overruns have been kept quite small due to the 
expertise that the Authority has developed over 25 years 
of experience, close monitoring of construction and a set 
of incentives designed to keep the contractor on 
schedule.  The incentives include $5,000 a day in bonuses 
for up to 20 days early completion and $15,000 a day in 
penalties for each day the project comes in late.


-27-

The enabling state legislation requires that the toll 
highways become free when all bonds and interest have 
been paid or the amounts necessary to do so have been put 
in reserve.  The state department of transportation would 
then assume responsibility for the roads' operation and 
maintenance.  This situation is not expected to occur 
before the year 2008.

Toll rates are set based on the annual rehabilitation 
plan of the Authority and on the semi-annual estimates of 
traffic engineering consultants. Revenues generated from 
tolls are invested in United States Treasury obligations.

Case Example - Florida

Florida has 13 toll roads which encompass 552 miles of 
highway, with the longest road, the Florida Turnpike, 
extending 321 miles.  There is one additional toll road 
under construction which will add another 23 miles to the 
total.

There are nine management structures that operate the 
various toll roads, unlike Illinois where one authority 
operates the state toll system, with the Florida 
Department of Transportation (FDOT) operating the Florida 
Turnpike. The other toll road managers are composed of 
either counties or independent authorities created by 
state legislation.

Since 1955, bonds totaling $1,013 billion have been 
issued in Florida for the financing of toll roads. 
Previously, once all indebtedness had been satisfied, a 
toll road became a free road in the state highway system. 
The Florida legislature changed this in 1985 so that 
tolls may be continued even after all obligations have 
been repaid. The resulting revenue may be used to build 
additional toll facilities or finance other 
transportation facilities.

Unlike Illinois or Texas, Florida's toll road bonds are 
backed by toll revenue and the full faith and credit of 
the state or county.  This latter provision


-28-

increases the marketability of the bonds by reducing the 
risk of default and lowering financing costs.  In 
essence, if toll revenue is not sufficient to pay off 
debt obligations, then state transportation funds may be 
used to make up the difference at the state level, and 
the county's portion of the state gasoline tax may be 
used at the county or authority level.  In the worst 
case, the state's general revenues are available for 
emergency repayments.

In 1984, the financial situation for Florida's toll roads 
was as follows:

	Toll revenue                              $120,285,000
	Revenues from concessions, interest,
	overweight tickets, miscellaneous
	(excluding bond receipts)                   39,020,000
	Total operating revenues                    59,305,000
	Total maintenance and operating expenditure 36,908,000
	Net operating revenues                     122,397,000

	The operating revenues have not been sufficient in 
recent years to pay off interest costs or for annual 
payments to retire the obligations.  Thus, the pledge by 
the state and county to back debt repayment has been used 
by a number of toll managers.  As of June 30, 1985, 
approximately $175 million was owed to the Florida 
Department of Transportation and the counties.  The FDOT 
has sought to put this into perspective by noting that it 
would cost $2 billion to purchase the rights-of-way and 
construct the toll roads today and that future revenues 
are expected to increase as traffic increases over time.  
In addition, the alternative of increasing toll rates 
would likely lead to decreased traffic and reduced 
revenues.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Toll Roads

Per Mile of New Toll Road Constructed (with current 
tolls) The Dallas North Tollway is 10 miles in length and 
will add 7.4 miles shortly.  Annual earnings currently 
more than cover annual costs, consisting of operating 
costs and interest on bond debt, which accounts for 
construction costs. The good


-29-

experience reflects high return on investment of revenue 
from the bonds. Annual costs per mile of tollway are 
approximately 1.3 million dollars per mile (covering both 
operating costs and interest on debt).  It seems 
reasonable to assume that considerable expansion in toll 
roads can take place at that cost, with annual revenues 
at least covering annual costs (even though interest from 
investment will decline as new construction takes place).

The estimates here are based on the Texas Turnpike 
Authority's 1986 financial statement for the tollway.  
For the fiscal year ended June 30, 1986, costs and toll 
revenue were approximately in balance, as follows:

		Toll revenues - 	   $13.4 million
		Operating costs - 	   $ 3.4 million
		Interest on tollway debt - $10.2 million

Hence, given the 10 mile length of the tollway, both 
earnings and total costs are approximately $1.3 million 
per mile.  (Note that costs include interest but exclude 
principal.)  However, the tollway also earned $10.7 
million from its investments, making it quite profitable 
- at least in 1986 (with a profit of $10.7 million on 
total revenue of $24.4 million).  But earnings from 
investments can be expected to decline, both because some 
of those invested funds will be used to pay for extending 
the tollway, and because the new federal tax law will 
likely limit returns on investments made with bond 
revenue.  To be cautious, it can be assumed that new 
tollways will earn no revenue on investment and will 
exactly pay for themselves at $1.3 million per mile.  
This yields the following revenue estimates.


-30-

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
			       Current     Increment
			       Level  Annual  Projected over
  Source of Revenue            (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level    Low -     High -
           	                               Annual   Annual
                                                x 24	x 36
______________________________________________________________

Additional Toll Roads at current Tolls

Per mile of additional tollway   1.3       1.3     31	  47
Per 10 additional miles          ---       13     310	 470
50 additional miles              ---       65    1560	2340

It is worth noting that the Trinity Tollway, if built, will be 
50+ miles.

Revenue Per Mile of Tollway with Increased Tolls The 
Dallas North Tollway charges passenger cars 5˘ per mile.  
Most rural tollroads charge passenger cars 1.5˘ to 3.0˘ 
per mile, with charges clustering around 2.2˘ per mile. 
Charges for trucks typically run 2 to 3 times the 
passenger car toll.

Some urban toll roads charge more than 5˘ per mile, 
including:

Florida -       Airport Expressway -    5.7˘
                Buccaneer Trail -       9.4˘
                East West Expressway - 12.5˘

Delaware -      JFK Memorial Hwy. - 6.7˘
Massachusetts - Boston Extension of Mass Turnpike - 6.3˘
Virginia -      Dulles Access Toll Road - 7.0˘

If toll rates are raised, available evidence indicates 
some loss in traffic volume, so total revenue will not 
rise proportionately, although it will increase.  The 
analysis runs as follows. From 1976 to 1982, a period of 
6 years, average daily vehicle trips on the Dallas North 
Tollway increased from 51,900 to 85,500.  The percentage 
increase was 65%.  During that period, because of 
inflation, the real value of tolls collected per trip 
dropped by about 40%.  On the basis of long term trends 
in use, the effect of the price drop was


-31-

established as leading to a 20% increase in vehicle use, 
with 37.5 percent having been explained as due to the 
increasing time trend in use (that is, 1.65/1.375 = 
1.20).  The time trend effect equaled about a 5 percent 
increase in use per year, presumably reflecting more 
intensive land use and trip generation, trip pattern 
change, etc. In 1982, the toll was doubled and vehicle 
trips decreased to about 78,000 as of 1985.  If the trend 
had continued, vehicle trips in 1985 could be expected to 
have been around 100,000.  The decrease between the 
expected value of 100,000 and the actual value of 78,000 
was consistent with a doubling of price, given the 
originally established price effect.  In technical terms, 
a price elasticity of -0.35 was estimated from the data, 
being consistent with both sets of changes.  That is, the 
price elasticity estimate obtained was consistent both 
with the effect of the real drop in price in the earlier 
period, and that of the real increase in price in the 
later period.  This price elasticity attributes greater 
impact to a price change than does anelasticity estimate of 
-.18 derived by Wilbur Smith and Associates in a 1985
study of the Dallas North Tollway.  The consequence of 
the price elasticity estimate of -0.35 is that a 50 percent
 increase in price leads to only a 30 percent increase in 
revenue because of a decline in use 
of 13 percent (that is 1.5 x 0.87 = 1.305).  Similarly, a 
doubling in price can be expected to lead to only a 57 
percent increase in revenue.  Given an estimated return 
of $1.3 million per mile for a 5˘ toll, a 50 per cent 
price increase to a 7.50 toll will yield $1.7 million per 
mile (1.3 x 1.305 = 1.7) for a net gain of $0.40 million.  
Similarly a doubling of the toll will yield a net gain of 
$0.75 million.  Estimates were obtained throughout 
assuming a relation of the form Q=KP-.35 where Q is 
quantity, P is price and K is a constant.) Summarizing 
these results then, the following estimates are obtained:


-32-

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
			       Current     Increment
			       Level  Annual  Projected over
  Source of Revenue            (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level    Low -     High -
           	                               Annual   Annual
                                                x 24	x 36
______________________________________________________________

      
Increases in Tolls

Revenue per mile of tollway

- 5˘ toll                       1.3     ---       ---	  ---
- 7.5˘ toll                     ---     0.40       9.6	  14.4
- 10˘ toll                      ---	0.75      18.0	  27.0

Note that the increments here should be added to the 
revenue increment per
additional mile of tollway at a toll of 5˘ per mile.  
Thus, at 10˘, the total revenue increment for 24 years is 
31 + 18 = 49 (million dollars).

Sources
Congressional Budget Office, Toll Financing of U.S. 
Highways, Congress of the United States, December 1985.

Federal Highway Administration, Highway Statistics 1984, 
DOT, FHWA, Washington, D. C.

General Accounting Office, Highway Funding: Use of Toll 
Revenues in Financing Highway Projects, April 1986. 
GAO/RCED-86-130.

International Bridge, Tunnel and Turnpike Association, 
Toll Rates Survey: U.S.and Canada Roads, Washington, D. 
C., July, 1985.

C. Kenneth Orski, "The Outlook For Urban Transportation", 
in Lester A. Hoel,
Editor, Innovative Financing For Transportation: 
Practical Solutions and
Experience, U.S. Department of Transportation, 
Washington, D. C., April 1986, pp. 33-34. (DOT-1-86-20).

Rice Center, Alternative Financing for Urban 
Transportation: State-of-the-Art Case Analyses, prepared 
for Federal Highway Administration and Urban Mass

Transportation Administration, Washington, D. C., Oct., 
1983 (DOT-1-83-54).

Rice Center, Joint Center for Urban Mobility, Financing 
Urban Transportation Improvements Report 3: A Guide to 
Alternative Financing Mechanisms for Urban Highways, 
prepared for Federal Highway Administration and Urban 
Mass Transportation Administration, Washington, D. C., 
June 1984.


-33-

Wilbur Smith and Associates, Dallas North Tollway and 
Extension, Phase I: Refinancing, Traffic and Revenues, 
October, 1985.

Texas Turnpike Authority, 1985 Annual Report.

Texas Turnpike Authority, "Financial Statement", June 30, 
1986.

Urban Consortium, Inflation-Responsive Financing for 
Streets and Highways, U.S. Department of Transportation 
6/82, DOT-1-82-56.

Contacts:   Neil Shuster, Executive Director 
	    International Bridge, Tunnel and Turnpike 
            Assoc. 2120 L Street, N. W., Suite 305 
            Washington, D. C. 20037 202-659-4620

            Harry Kabler, C.P.A., Secretary-Treasurer 
            Texas Turnpike Authority 
            3015 Raleigh Street 
            P.O. Box 190369 
            Dallas, TX 75219 
            214-522-1964


-34-

		IB. ELECTRONIC ROAD PRICING
			   Detail
Background

Attempts at road pricing experiments in the United States 
have not been encouraging.  Thomas Higgins notes that 
starting in 1976, the Secretary of the U.S. Department of 
Transportation, William T. Coleman, wrote the mayors of 
several cities about the availability of a road pricing 
demonstration, involving window stickers or a license 
scheme.  A number of the mayors rejected the idea 
outright, including the mayors of Rochester, N.Y., 
Atlanta, Seattle and Baltimore.  The mayor of Baltimore 
wrote: "For a downtown area which is struggling to 
maintain its competitive position with suburban 
centers... with vast amounts of free parking, I am 
concerned over any proposal which would further weaken 
the position of Baltimore's downtown area." Only Madison, 
Wisconsin; Berkeley, California; and Honolulu were 
willing to entertain the idea.   In all three cases that 
entertainment was short-lived, and the demonstrations 
were never carried out.  In Berkeley, there was some 
distorted media attention which led many to believe that 
pricing would apply to all places and times, contrary to 
the view that free road use was a basic right.   In 
general, rejection of the demonstration in the three 
cities was based on the perceptions that pricing would 
involve coercive interference with travel rights, harm to 
business and regressive impacts on the poor.

However, the public appears least resistant to road 
pricing when it is presented as a user fee to support 
roads, possibly taking the place of taxes.  Electronic 
pricing has become feasible, and can also improve public 
acceptance by relating charges to peak load times and 
places.  For that reason, in considering application to 
revenue needs in the NCTCOG area, there is focus on 
expressway travel, with particular attention to peak load 
travel.


-35-

Case Study: The Coronado Bridge Experiment

The California State Department of Transportation 
(CalTrans) is experimenting with a system called 
"Automatic Vehicle Identification" or AVI for short, in 
collecting tolls at the Coronado Bridge in San Diego 
County, California.  The system consists of sensing 
devices attached to automobiles which return an 
electronic signal to a computer at the toll collection 
point.  The computer identifies the signal as being from 
a particular car that is registered in the data bank.  To 
register a vehicle for participation in the experiment, 
the vehicle owner must be willing to be billed for the 
charges that he incurs.

The advantages of this system for the vehicle owner is 
that it allows him to proceed through a toll collection 
point with minimal delay.  The system has a potential 
capacity far above the 400 cars per hour per man rate of 
an individual toll collector, and the 600 cars per hour 
per automatic toll collector machine.  The individual 
also has the benefit of paying a single bill, which 
alleviates the problems of carrying change or of waiting 
for a toll collector to make change.

A major prospective advantage of the system is that it 
has the potential for saving 10% per year in salaries of 
toll collectors, although this savings has yet to be 
demonstrated in the experiment.  The final cost savings 
will be shown in an evaluation report due out during 
1987.  The second prospective advantage is that the 
system should substantially alleviate the congestion at 
toll plazas during peak hours.

The original cost of the experimental system will range 
somewhere between $500,000 and $800,000, excluding such 
items as additional lanes.  The system


-36-

is under development by Science Applications International, 
which currentlyis carrying out accuracy tests on the systems 
operation.  Attention is being directed to questions such as 
where in or on the automobile should theidentification tag be 
placed? Other questions turn on the number and height of the 
transmitting antenna.  Tests found that initially 13% of the 
targetautomobiles could not be fitted with the identification 
tag; over half of these cars had an iron compound in 
their windshields which upset the transmissions.

The questions of compliance with the billings has yet to 
be tested.  One possible mechanism for billing is to 
place the charge on the customers' VISA and Mastercard 
accounts.  Another possibility is to bill quarterly. For 
people who do not pay their bills, adding the costs to 
their vehicle registration fees is a possibility.

The question on the mix of AVI stations, automatic toll 
collectors, and regular toll collector stations has not 
been addressed.  Neither has the cost of maintenance of 
the AVI system been estimated.

Case Study: Hong Kong Pilot Project

Over the period 1983-1985, the Hong Kong government 
commissioned a pilot study to examine the viability of 
electronic road pricing (ERP) in the territory.  Dawson 
and Catling studied the workings of the project and 
concluded that ERP offers a highly efficient and 
equitable method of dealing with Hong Kong's intense 
traffic problems.  The system reduces traffic on 
congested roads without penalizing drivers on uncongested 
roads, and gives people free choice in the selection of 
their trip routes.


-37-

The ERP system works as follows.  A small, inexpensive, 
solid state device, termed an "electronic number plate", 
is attached to the underside of each vehicle. Once 
fitted, it requires no manual intervention and is 
maintenance free.

A series of charge zones is defined for the area covered 
by electronic user charges; in the Hong Kong urban area, 
there were approximately 200 zones.  At each zone 
boundary crossing, an array of loops is buried in the 
road surface.  As a vehicle passes over those loops, its 
electronic number plate is energized, and its crossing is 
recorded.  The number plate transmits a string of data at 
each crossing, with a unique security coded 
identification employed for each vehicle.  Tolls per zone 
range from around 10˘ to $1.50 (in U.S. currency).  
Presumably a motorist will cross several zones during his 
trip, so single trip costs will be a sum of zone tolls.  
Tolls are cumulated by means of an inexpensive 
microcomputer system and at the end of the month, each 
vehicle owner is sent a statement of his road user 
charges, in a form similar to a credit card statement.  
Motorist needs for privacy are maintained by making 
listings on the statement of charges as circumscribed and 
limited as the user desires.  The results have been 
accurate and reliable and Hong Kong expects to develop 
full scale use of the system by the end of the decade, 
starting with the registering of tolls as the entrance to 
tunnels.

Toll authorities around the world have been investigating 
electronic road pricing for some years.  Benefits include 
reduction of traffic congestion, increased revenue 
collections, and reduced costs, with replacement of 
salaried toll collectors with automatic sensors.  In 
addition, there are a number of likely side benefits, 
including the potential for automatic traffic data


-38-

collection. Such data will be useful both as real-time 
traffic flow information (for police and journey-to-work 
travelers) and as data to be used for analytic purposes, 
from setting signal times to making highway investment 
decisions.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Electronic Road Pricing 
Weekday vehicle miles of travel (VMT) in a previous 
version of the NCTCOG planning area (The Intensive Study 
area) were 77.17 million per day, as of 1985, distributed 
as 33.76 million VMT on freeways, 36.32 million VMT on 
arterials and 7.09 million VMT on local roads.  To obtain 
an annual figure, daily travel is
multiplied by 340 (instead of the usual 365 days) 
accounting for somewhat lower volume on weekend days.  To 
convert to levels corresponding to the current NCTCOG 
transportation planning area, volumes are multiplied by 
1.05. Volumes per year then become 27.55 billion VMT in 
total, distributed as 12.05 billion VMT on freeways, 
12.97 billion VMT on arterials and 2.53 billion VMT on 
local roads.  If pricing were limited to the 12.05 
billion VMT on freeways, the following revenue would be 
obtained:
______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
			       Current     Increment
			       Level  Annual  Projected over
  Source of Revenue            (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level    Low -     High -
           	                               Annual   Annual
                                                x 24	x 36
______________________________________________________________

Electronic Pricing

- At 0.1˘ per VMT on freeways    ---       12.0     288	   432
- At   1˘ per VMT on freeways    ---      120.0    2880	  4320
- If peakload travel on freeways 
  is 0.4 of daily VMT, and the      
  charge is 1˘ per VMT           ---       48.0    1152	  1728
- A charge of 50 per VMT during 
  peak load travel, again 
  assuming 0.4 of daily VMT on 
  freeways is peak load.        ---       240.0    5760	  8640


-39-

Sources

Background: Thomas J. Higgins, "Road Pricing Attempts in 
the United States," Transportation Research-A, Vol. 20A, 
No 2, March 1986, 145-150.

Coronado Bridge: Contacts

California Department of Transportation - District 11
William Dotson, Director
James Gray, Deputy Director for Maintenance and Operations
Stewart Shuga, AVI Project Engineer
2829 Juan
P.O. Box 85406
San Diego, California 82138-5406

Thomas McDaniel
Science Applications International
10210 Campus Point Drive
San Diego, California 92121

Hong Kong Pilot Project: References

J. A. L. Dawson and I. Catling, "Electronic Road Pricing 
in Hong Kong", Transportation Research-A, Vol. 20A, No. 
2, March 1986, 129-134.

Steven A. Morrison, "A Survey of Road Pricing", 
Transportation Research-A, Vol. 20A, No. 2, March 1986, 
87-95; see 94-95 in particular, for a discussion of the 
Hong Kong pilot project.

Vehicle Miles of Travel: North Central Texas Council of 
Governments "Weekday
VMT Summary Report, 1977-1985", Revised 5/20/86.


-40-

		II. JOINT PUBLIC-PRIVATE FINANCING
			    Overview

The heading of Joint Public-Private Financing covers a 
number of current activities and suggested activities 
that have generated a great deal of interest.  Those that 
are included in this review are cataloged under the 
subheadings of Development Impact Fees, Benefit 
Assessment Districts, Leasing or Sale of Development 
Rights or Air Rights, and Developer Contributions through 
Negotiations.  In all these cases, there is a recognition 
of the interaction between new highway construction and 
real estate development.  The recognition may take the 
form of a policy of charging for additional traffic or 
transportation capacity generated by new development; or 
it may take the form of a policy of capturing some of the 
benefits generated by new highways, particularly the 
benefits of land value appreciation.  Although these 
policies have apparently differing justifications, and 
their implementation is carried out by many different 
mechanisms, their rationale seems basically the same: it 
is proper to hold private sector interests accountable 
for the benefits they derive from highway development, 
and for the costs they impose in taking advantage of 
those benefits.  The sources behind this rationale 
include recognition of and response to current financial 
stringencies; growing acceptance of the "user pays" 
principle; the trend to privatization; and a recasting of 
the "no-growth" advocacy position.  Although many 
developers and real estate owners have resisted 
contributing to highway funding, a number now accept that 
arrangement, and considerable revenue has been raised 
thereby.


-41-

		II.A. DEVELOPMENT IMPACT FEES
			Overview

Definition

Impact fees are fees imposed on private sector developers 
to mitigate the impacts of new projects on local 
services.  Since new developments increase congestion, 
private developers should help pay for solutions which 
mitigate the congestion.  As a condition for obtaining 
site plan approval or building permits, fees of various 
amounts can be imposed on a one time basis, or they may 
be imposed in the form of an annual tax.  Both forms are 
usually based on the square footage of the new 
development.  The actual size of the impact fee will vary 
based on percentage of total costs for which the private 
developers are to be held responsible.

Examples

San Francisco, CA (San Francisco County Board of 
Supervisors, Finance Bureau of the Public Utilities 
Commission).  Sacramento, CA (Sacramento County Planning 
Department).  Portland, OR (County Planning Commission, 
TRI-MET). Farmers Branch, TX (Richardson, TX is 
considering the introduction of impact fees.)

Financial Results

Revenue potential for transportation impact fees can be 
very substantial. This revenue can be generated on a 
one-time basis or can be generated over a number of 
years.  The San Francisco program imposes a $5 per square 
foot fee on a one-time basis and will have an estimated 
revenue potential of $37 million once it clears legal 
hurdles hindering implementation.  It should be noted 
that very high fees may have the undesirable effect of 
causing private developers to relocate or abandon plans 
or perhaps contest the fees in court.  These effects 
could lower the financial benefits of the fees.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative Local ordinances are required.  
  These ordinances are subject to challenges from 
  property owners and developers who claim they are 
  being required to pay more than their fair share of 
  the cost of transportation improvements.  
  Negotiated requirements raise questions about 
  conditions being attached to zoning approvals.  
  Litigation questioning the legality of impact fees 
  Francisco.

  Political Developers and property owners contend 
  the fees discourage growth and impose unfair 
  economic burdens on them but not on earlier 
  development projects.  If the fee is applied 
  retroactively to approved development plans it will 
  be viewed as an unfair additional expense by 
  earlier developers.

  Economic It is equitable to make problem creators 
  pay for the solutions of those problems.  However, 
  impact fees may not be efficient if they inhibit 
  development, and high enough fees will do so.  (If 
  growth limitations are desired, high impact fees 
  will serve well in achieving that end.)  The fees 
  are well suited to obtaining revenue for highway 
  extensions and expansions.


-42-

	II.B. BENEFIT ASSESSMENT DISTRICTS

			Overview
Definition

A benefit assessment is a tax or fee placed on property 
within the boundaries of a district which has benefited 
from some particular improvements including 
transportation investments such as highways and transit 
systems.  Benefit assessment revenue is used to pay for 
all or part of the cost of the specific improvement made 
within the district and can be used to secure and retire 
the bonds financing the improvements.  Fee revenue may 
also be used to fund maintenance and operating costs.  
Special assessments may be either one-time or recurring 
charges.

Examples
Denver, CO (Rapid Transit District in Denver, Downtown 
Denver, Inc.). 
Miami, FL (Dade County Transportation Administration). 
Los Angeles, CA (Southern California Rapid Transit 
District). Houston, TX (Harris County)

Financial Results

Actual assessments are based on (a) annual costs of debt 
service or operations, and (b) estimates of the value of 
the benefits to the property located within the district 
- this is often done on a sliding scale, based on 
proximity to the improvements and expected increases in 
property values due to improvements.  The range of fees 
typically runs from 5˘ to 45˘ per square foot for the 
annual assessments.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative State enabling legislation is 
  required before a transportation agency or other 
  local government can levy special assessment fees.  
  Intergovernmental agreements may be required for a 
  transportation agency in order for it to receive 
  assessment revenues. If sliding scales are used it 
  is necessary to develop rational formulae for 
  delineating the location of rate changes.

  Political Capital costs may be more politically 
  feasible than operational costs in gaining approval 
  for benefit assessments. Developers and property 
  owners may argue for lowering fee rates since it is 
  difficult to determine special benefits (as opposed 
  to costs). The method permits financing without 
  creating a new area wide tax, which may be 
  politically advantageous.

  Economic Assessments employ the user fee principle: 
  those who benefit pay and those who benefit most 
  pay the most.  Of course, those singled out as 
  beneficiaries usually prefer the costs to be spread 
  to the larger community.  If beneficiaries do not 
  think the improvements are worth paying for, then 
  setting up districts can be postponed.  Benefit 
  assessment districts are usually employed in 
  central business districts or transit station areas 
  but could work with property owners and businesses 
  on or near highways.


-43-

	II.C. LEASE/SALE OF DEVELOPMENT RIGHTS OR AIR RIGHTS

			  Overview
Definition

Transportation agencies may lease or sell development 
rights for the space above or adjacent to their land 
holdings and facilities.  They can lease space above rail 
and bus stations, and above highways.  This space may be 
used to build hotels, office and retail facilities.  
Adjacent space can be offered to neighboring businesses 
interested in improving access to the transportation 
site.

Examples

Boston, MA (Massachusetts Turnpike Authority).  Miami, FL 
(Office of Transportation Administration for Metropolitan 
Dade County).  Sparks, NV (Nevada State Highway 
Department).  Washington, D. C. (Washington Metropolitan 
Area Transit Authority).  State of California 
(Caltrans-California Department of Transportation).

Financial Results

Leasing or selling air rights or development rights to 
adjacent space is a method of generating substantial 
amounts of revenue for transportation systems.  It is 
usually deemed preferable to lease development rights 
rather than sell them.  This provides continual income 
for the life of the lease rather than a one time payment.  
Funds can be used for operating expenses or to finance 
future capital investments.  Whether sold or leased the 
development property should have the additional benefit 
of contributing to the property and/or tax base of the 
community.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative The sale of development rights 
  may require enabling legislation.  Leases need 
  approval of many governmental parties.  Alternative 
  proposals via competitive bidding legally may be 
  required.  If there are rent terms beyond a fixed 
  sum, it is easier to negotiate leases based upon 
  gross projected revenues rather than actually 
  monitored profits.

  Political Losers from any proposal requiring 
  competitive bidding may litigate the transportation 
  agency's decision to award the lease to another 
  party.  This can delay the project, raise costs and 
  lower actual revenues.  State laws and local laws 
  may conflict in such cases.  Area residents may 
  oppose sales or leasing if they are not consulted 
  on the design and impact of development.  Community 
  approval of the project may take many meetings.

  Economic Large projects favor large developers and 
  may be inaccessible to small and minority 
  development groups without special consideration 
  being given those groups.  Development can benefit 
  both employers and their employees by providing 
  prime location real estate to developers, office 
  and retail space to employers and transportation 
  facilities to workers.  Use has primarily been at 
  transit stations, although some highway use has 
  occurred.


-44-

     II.D. DEVELOPER CONTRIBUTIONS THROUGH NEGOTIATIONS
MECHANISM (1) - LEASING OF LAND AT LOW RATES AND LAND DONATIONS
			Overview

Definition

Leasing property may be one method to reduce costs of 
land acquisition for a transportation agency or 
government.  Negotiated land leases are agreements 
between private developers/property owners and the 
transportation agency/local government under which land 
is leased for a nominal charge in order to allow 
construction of transportation facilities.  It may also 
be possible for local governments and transportation 
agencies to successfully solicit donations of land from 
the private sector to permit transportation improvements 
to be made.  A well organized and highly visible campaign 
can locate multiple donors of land who are willing to 
contribute some of their holdings.

Examples

Takoma, WA (Pierce Transit Planning Office).  Phoenix, AZ 
(Phoenix Transit).  Grand Rspids, MI (Grand Rapids Area 
Transit Authority).

Financial Results

The major benefit is the cost saving of not having to buy 
land or condemn land for transportation purposes.  A 
combination of donations and long term leases at low rent 
can significantly reduce costs of highway construction in
metropolitan areas.  There are examples of leasing for 20 
to 30 years at $1 per year per parcel.  But opponents to 
highway construction/expansion may limit use of the 
method.

Major Issues 

  Legal/Administrative  For leases, transportation 
   agencies need authority to contract with private 
  property owners.  There are no known legal problems 
  with donations.

  Political The approach necessitates close 
  leasing process.  There is rarely any public 
  opposition to leasing land.  Acquiring land through 
  donation requires exceptional persuasive powers and 
  political sensitivity, particularly if more than 
  one landowner has the needed property.  Donations 
  are unlikely to raise public opposition.

  Economic The method is efficient, but can pose 
  implementation problems.  It is also equitable as 
  donors or leasors are usually large 
  landowners/developers who are providing a small 
  portion of their holdings in order to increase the 
  value of the rest of their property.  Progress may 
  be impeded by the high number of private parcels 
  needed.


-45-

	II.D. DEVELOPER CONTRIBUTIONS THROUGH NEGOTIATIONS
		MECHANISM (2) - LEASE/SELL FACILITIES
			Overview

Definition

Once a local government has full interest in a property 
it can dispose of any portions which are not needed for 
transportation purposes.  Local governments and 
transportation agencies should consider vacant or 
under-utilized property as a potential source of revenue 
through sales or leasing arrangements with the private 
sector.  For new or future development it may be 
desirable to plan for additional building space which can 
then be leased.  It is normally preferable to lease 
rather than sell facilities unless government authorities 
can safely determine that such facilities will no longer 
be needed in the future.  Funds are used to offset 
operating expenses of the leased facility.

Examples

Santa Cruz, CA (Santa Cruz Metropolitan Transit 
District). Fargo, ND (City of Fargo).

Financial Results

Leasing or selling facilities is a method of generating 
relatively modest amounts of revenue.  Revenues depend on 
the availability of facilities which are under-utilized, 
and the local real estate market in that area.  Private 
sector leases agree to lease the facility for a given 
time period for a fixed rate and to pay for improvements 
to the property.  Both parties determine how utilities 
are to be paid.  In the cases cited, revenues roughly 
equalled operating costs in one case (Fargo) and were 
less than operating costs in another (Santa Cruz).

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative Transportation agencies and 
  local governments need special authority to dispose 
  of facilities no longer needed for transportation 
  purposes.  Revenue potential may be reduced by a 
  need to turn a percentage over to UMTA or other 
  government organizations if the projects to be 
  leased were partially financed with UMTA or other 
  government funds. UMTA, HUD and others have allowed 
  such agreements, however.

  Political Proposals to lease or sell transit 
  facilities are not likely to be opposed by local 
  community organizations.  This type of revenue 
  measure may slow down transportation funds from 
  UMTA.  In the North Dakota case it took four years 
  to get UMTA funds released.

  Economic When unneeded facilities can be leased or 
  sold the private sector benefits by obtaining a 
  facility it wants, the transportation agency or 
  government receives additional revenue and citizens 
  may receive additional services at no cost.  All 
  parties can benefit.  There has been limited 
  applicability to date in public transportation and 
  the approach is likely to be more applicable to 
  transit facilities than to highway facilities.


	II. D. DEVELOPER CONTRIBUTIONS THROUGH NEGOTIATIONS
		MECHANISM (3) - AD HOC NEGOTIATIONS

				Overview

Definition

A variety of specific negotiations can be carried out 
between government agencies and private organizations, 
particularly developers.  Government agencies can bargain 
using discretionary development approvals.

Examples

Three California cases - two in Southern California and 
one in Northern California - involve major developer 
contributions.  Texas Transportation Corporations can be 
subsumed under this heading.

Financial Results

The California cases involved contributions ranging from 
$60 to $80 million. Of course, these occurred within the 
context of major developments, running around one billion 
dollars each.  Hence, the level of contribution ran from 
6 to 8% of the development cost.

Major Issues

Legal/Administrative There are a variety of legal 
constraints on local government negotiations 
regarding development requirements.  This leads to 
the question "Why Not Buy and Sell 
Zoning...legally, that is?"

Political Private developers may be more 
experienced and sophisticated than public officials 
in the negotiation process, or at least members of 
the public may think so.

Economic The flexibility afforded by ad hoc 
bargaining may improve chances of working out an 
agreement acceptable to all parties.


-47-

		II. JOINT PUBLIC-PRIVATE FINANCING
				Detail
Background

There is growing interest and more important, stepped-up 
activity, under the heading of joint public-private financing 
of highways.1

The reasons for this growth likely include the following.

(1)  Financial Stringency. In an era of fiscal restraint, 
     both at the state and local level (e.g. 
     California's Proposition 13) and at the federal 
     level (e.g. Gramm-Rudman-Hollings), there is an 
     increasing need for creativity in meeting revenue 
     goals.

(2)  Demographic Changes. Population increase is 
     approaching a zero-population-growth rate, greatly 
     reducing overall interest in and pressure for new 
     roads at the national level.  Yet, in most large 
     urban areas, population and industry continue their 
     suburban shift, generating a discerned need for new 
     highways in suburban locations.

(3)  User Pays Principle. There seems increasing 
     recognition of the proposition that the user or 
     beneficiary of a service ought to pay for that 
     service.  In highway finance, this involves a 
     considerable shift from the view that the community 
     at large ought to pay for highway facilities, a 
     view that wee a basic element of postwar policy, 
     beginning with the Federal Aid Highway Act of 1956, 
     which established the National Interstate and 
     Defense Highway System.

     It is plausible that the voting public has become 
     increasingly disillusioned with a lack of 
     accountability in general taxation-based financing, 
     leading to the positive reception of the user-pays 
     principle.2


-48-

(4)  Privatization. There is a general trend toward 
     privatization, and to the extent that developers begin to
     play a direct role in highway planning and policy as a 
     result of explicitly bearing some of the costs, the 
     privatization motive may come into play in direct 
     fashion.3

(5)  Modifying of No Growth Stance. Persons advocating 
     the limiting or cessation of urban growth have recently 
     tended to moderate and modify their position, viewing such
     devices as impact fees as more modest and realistic 
     instruments to slow growth than the use of direct 
     controls.4

There are some causal issues that should be addressed in 
considering joint public-private financing.  Impact fees 
are a means of mitigating or compensating for the 
"negative" effects of new development, which adds traffic 
to the highway system and thus increases congestion and a 
need for increased government spending to ameliorate the 
congestion.  However, new buildings typically will be 
built in response to new highways having been built, or 
because of changing economic circumstances making both 
highways and development worthwhile; that is, highways 
either cause development or both highways and development 
are caused by the same external source, but development, 
to proceed, must have the access furnished by highways.  
Benefit assessment districts, leasing or sale of 
development rights or air rights, and developer 
contributions through negotiations explicitly recognize 
this contribution of highways to land development and 
increased land value.5  New highways have caused 
development  along or near those highways to become 
profitable, or more profitable than they were, by 
increasing access to the land along or near the highways.  
Hence, impact fees or benefit assessments can be viewed 
as a response to the same
process. Of course, "costs" are seen as "negative" or 
"bad", and benefits are seen as "positive" or "good", but 
both perspectives might be viewed as somewhat


-49-

partial.  It is presumed here that on balance, the 
benefits outweigh the costs, and further, that developer 
responses adding to "costs" are part of the movement to a 
long run equilibrium of traffic generation and 
development induced by new highways.

Many developers and real estate owners have resisted 
participating in the raising of highway revenue, seeing 
that participation as a form of legal extortion.  
However, there appears to be growing acceptance of the 
proposition that such participation may be the only means 
of building new highways that the private participants 
would like to see built.  Acceptance is strengthened when 
costs can be passed on to tenants or consumers, which is 
often the case.  In practice, private participation has 
resulted in a good deal of revenue for highways, which 
will be demonstrated below.


-50-

Footnotes

1.   Useful reviews of both the literature and of activities 
     appear in Lester Hoel, Innovative Financing for 
     Transportation: Practical Solutions and Experiences, U. S.
     Department of Transportation, Washington, D. C., April, 
     1986 (DOT 1-86-20) and in C. Kenneth Orski, "Suburban 
     Mobility:  The Coming Transportation Crisis", 
     Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 39, No 2, April 1983, 
     283-296.

2.   Robert C. Schaevitz makes this point in Hoel, 
     Innovative Financing, p. 173. 1

3.   Orski argues that developers, landlord and employees 
     are in far better position than public agencies to 
     influence individual commuters' travel habits. (His 
     paper in Hoel, Innovative Financing, pp. 3-31.)

4.   James Duncan and Norman Standerfer, Impact Fees: The 
     Changing Direction of Growth Management, Austin, 
     Texas, November, 1985.

5.   Orski points out that assessed value of property may 
     not bear a relation to traffic generation 
     ("Suburban Mobility..." p. 290).  But such a 
     nonrelationship is unusual; typically, value and 
     traffic levels are highly correlated.


-51-

		II.A. DEVELOPMENT IMPACT FEES
			Detail

General Experience

The use of impact fees for highway financing is reputed 
to have been first employed in the fast growing areas of 
Florida and California (Schmidt, 1985).  In addition to those 
states, current examples include Colorado, Maryland, New Jersey 
and Oregon (Orski, 1985, 289).

When first employed, impact fees were tied specifically 
to the impact of a particular development on traffic.  
But there has been some tendency to widen the geographic 
responsibility of private contributions, so the 
relationship between a given development's impact on 
traffic and the fee it is charged becomes fuzzy and 
diffuse.  In California and Florida, the initial pattern 
prevails on the basis of court rulings that any fees 
levied on new development must be earmarked for purposes 
benefiting those who pay the fees (Orski, 1985, 291).  In 
New Jersey, by contrast, developers pay fees related to 
state-wide highway development.

Impact fees will have greatest applicability and yield 
the highest revenue in areas with considerable new 
development.  Hence, it is not too surprising that in the 
local financing of highways in California, impact fees 
tend to be used in growth areas, while local option sales 
taxes are used in stable areas.

The magnitude of fees charged can vary a great deal. But 
this is not surprising when land values are compared; 
land values in the central business district of large 
cities are some orders of magnitude above land values at 
urban peripheries.  Thus, in reviewing California 
experience with impact fees, Reid and Winkler report that 
San Francisco charges $5,000, Escondido charges no more 
than $400 and Simi Valley charges only $55 per 1,000 
square feet of new office


-52-

space.  In addition to differences in land values, 
differences in receptivity to growth probably play an 
important role, since areas resisting growth will tend to 
charge higher fees.

Fees can be charged annually or on a one time basis.  
Berkeley, California charges 200 per square foot of 
development for 30 years to cover "traffic system 
management plans".  Cities charging a one-time fee 
include Irvine, at $6 per square foot; San Francisco at 
$5 per square foot; and Orange County at $3.75 per square 
foot, all for commercial development.

Some fees are charged on the basis of trips generated, 
rather than on the basis of square feet of development, 
but usually there is a conversion rule that translates 
square feet into trips.  Los Angeles is considering 
charging $2,010 per evening rush hour trip generated by 
developments within the Coastal Corridor Transportation 
Plan area (Reid and Winkler, p. 194).  This has been 
estimated to correspond to $6.18 per square foot of 
office space, assuming that 1000 square feet of office 
space generate 12.3 trips and that one fourth of the 
trips occur in the evening rush hour.  Further, Los 
Angeles plans to impose an impact fee of $5,650 per peak 
hour trip generation for development within a six block 
area that runs along Wilshire Boulevard just south of 
UCLA.  Orange County also uses a trip generation basis 
for some of its impact fees, in some cases charging as 
much as $5,000 per peak hour trip generated.

Both costs borne by developers and their share of total 
project costs can be quite high.  Orange County's major 
application of impact fees takes the form of "corridor 
fees" to be imposed on developments served by three new 
freeways - the San Joaquin Freeway, the Eastern Freeway, 
and a freeway paralleling the Santa Anna Freeway.  The 
Irvine Company is the major developer in the area, and it 
seems likely it will pass the impact costs on to its 
customers.  The corridor


-53-

fees are estimated to equal $630 million, roughly half 
the costs of the new highways. (Orski's estimate is 60%, 
[1986, p. 35]; Straton's is 40: as the developer's share 
- see the appendix to this report.)

In Montgomery County, Maryland, developers have proposed 
an "impact fee district" to raise 50 percent of the cost 
(approximately $75 million) of transportation 
improvements in a rapidly expanding part of the County. 
Annual fees will extend over 20 years, and the annual fee 
obligation will constitute alien on the property.

Highway impact fees are not limited to charges on 
commercial and industrial land use.  Orange County, for 
example, charges $1,250 per new residential unit.  More 
generally, some California cities have very detailed 
lists allocating particular levels of impact fees for 
very specific land uses, as shown in Table 6.

Local Application of Impact Fees

A number of cities in Texas have instituted capital 
recovery fees, a form of impact fees, usually for water and 
sewer lines.  Most of the cities have relatively small 
populations, with Plano the largest city having a fee system
in place.  (For a detailed survey of Texas experience, see Pugh
et. al.). 

Plano uses "lot development fees" to account for the 
additional costs of increasing the capacity of water and 
sewer systems in response to increasing demand.  Plano 
was one of the first of the local area governments to 
implement an impact fee system, and that system has 
yielded a moderate amount of revenue.


-54-

			         TABLE 6

		TRAFFIC IMPACT FEES IN CALIFORNIA

City		Fee Description

Escondido	Traffic Impact Fee

	Residential	$395 to $790/DU
	Commercial/Retail	$800 to $10,000/1000 sq.ft.
	Offices			$400 to $1,800/1000 sq.ft.
	Banking			$1,200 to $6,000/1000 sq.ft.
	Industrial		$60 to $200/1000 sq.ft.
	Automotive		$1,200 to $15,000/1000 sq.ft.
	Recreational 		varies
	Restaurants		$2,000 to S12,000/l000 sq.ft.
	Church			$600/l000 sq.ft. of Main 
                                  Sanctuary
	Day Care		$40/student
 	Elementary Sch/Jr. High $20/student
	Hospital                $400/1000 sq. ft. or $60/bed

Lancaster	Traffic Signals Fee
		Residential zones             $96/DU
		Multiple Residential zones        96/DU
		Commercial zones            2,181.95/gr.ac.
		Industrial/Manufacturing      378.20/gr.ac.

Los Angeles 	Traffic Impact Fee of $2010/evening
		rush hour trip generated by a development 
		within the Coastal Corridor Transportation Plan
		area

		Los Angeles Regional Transit District plans to 
		impose a Tax Increment Financing arrangement on
		commercial properties near proposed metro rail
		subway stations.

Manhattan	Parking-in-lieu fee for commercial developments
Beach		in downtown business district @ $15,000/
		required parking space (number of required 
		parking spaces unspecified in materials 
		received)

Orange County 	Traffic Impact Fee for new freeway construction 
		@ $1250/new  residential unit 
		@ $3.75/sq.ft. on new commercial space built 
		within several square miles of the proposed 
		San Joaquin Hills and Foothill/Eastern 
		transportation corridor

Rancho		Street and Highway Systems Fee @ 1% of 
Cucamonga	building valuation 

San Diego	San Diego Transit traded density to certain 
		developers for $100,000 to help pay for the 
		Mission Viejo rail line.

San Francisco 	Traffic Impact Fee of $5/sq.ft. of development 
		on new downtown office construction to finance 
		improvements to the City's public 
		transportation system (imposed as of 1981).

Santee 		Traffic Impact Fee of $76/estimated trips for 
		development + Traffic Signal Fee of $6.67/
		estimated trips for dev.


-55-

			TABLE 6 (continued)
		TRAFFIC IMPACT FEES IN CALIFORNIA

Simi Valley Traffic Signal Construction Fee

Land Use			Fee

Single Family Detached House  $44.50/Dwelling Unit (DU)	
Condominium/Townhouse         22.50/DU
Mobile Home                   11.00/DU
Apartment                     12.50/DU
Hotel                         47.00/room
Hotel                         45.50/room
Industrial                    24.00/1000 sq.ft.
Warehouse                     22.50/1000 sq.ft.
Light Manufacturing           18.00/1000 sq.ft.

Shopping Center:
a. <50,000 sq.ft.            515.50
b. 50,000 to 99,000 sq.ft.   25,775 + $188.50/sq.ft.>50,000
c. 100,000 to 100,999 sq.ft. 35,000 + $186.00/sq.ft.>100,000
d. 200,000 to 499,999 sq.ft. 53,800 + $120.50/sq.ft.>200,000
e. 500,000 sq.ft. +          89,950 + $97.00/sq.ft.>500,000
Service Station               3,329.00/1000 sq.ft.
Drug Store                      195.50/1000 sq.ft.
Discount Store                  287.50/1000 sq.ft.
Supermarket                     558.50/1000 sq.ft.
Convenience Market            2,570.00/1000 sq.ft.
Clothing Store                  139.50/1000 sq.ft.
Hardware Store                  228.50/1000 sq.ft.
Variety Store                    64.00/1000 sq.ft.
Furniture Store                  25.00/1000 sq.ft.
Department Store                 113.50/1000 sq.ft.
Savings and Loan                 271.50/1000 sq.ft.
Bank-Walk-in                     752.00/1000 sq.ft.
Bank-Drive-in                    854.50/1000 sq.ft.
Restaurant-Quality               250.50/1000 sq.ft.
Restaurant-High turnover/sitdown 732.00/1000 sq.ft.
Restaurant-fast food           2,461.00/1000 sq.ft.
Hospital                          75.50/1000 sq.ft.
Nursing Home                      12.00/1000 sq.ft.
Medical Office                   334.00/1000 sq.ft.
General Office                    55.00/1000 sq.ft.
Office Park                       92.00/1000 sq.ft.
Research Center                   41.50/1000 sq.ft.
Civic Center                     111.50/1000 sq.ft.
Racquet Club                      40.00/1000 sq.ft.
Medical Clinic                    26.50/1000 sq.ft.

Stockton     Traffic Signals District Fee (unspecified)

Yorba Linda  Eastside Street Improvement Fees @  $600/unit


Source: Gary J. Reid and Donald R. Winkler "User Fees 
        Among Cities in Los Angeles County and The Rest 
        of Southern California", a report to the Los Angeles 
        Taxpayers Association, Aug. 6, 1986, pp. 195-6.


-56-

The pattern of fees charged in Plano, over time, is as follows:
	
FEE DEVELOPMENT	    RESIDENTIAL         NONRESIDENTIAL

1978 (established)  $50                     --
1982	            $100         $10 per 1000 sq. ft. (approx.)
1985	            $300         $30 per 1000 sq. ft.

Fees were tripled in 1985, yet this has not increased 
revenue collected because of the recent slowdown in 
residential and commercial development. Despite the 
increase in rates, the Plano rate structure is now 
relatively low, compared to nearby cities, so this may be 
a feature that developers find attractive.

Both the cities of Richardson and of Farmers Branch are 
exploring the use of impact fees in transportation 
development.  Richardson recently retained a consulting 
firm to explore the viability of such fees (the report 
was positive) and prepared a model ordinance to implement 
the fees. Farmers Branch has written and passed 
ordinances to charge impact fees for a number of 
infrastructure items (water and sewer facilities, 
landscaping and land improvements), as well as for 
transportation improvements. Of direct interest, Farmers 
Branch is planning to charge a one-time fee of 50˘ per 
square foot for new construction near the LBJ Freeway.  
This is a modest amount compared to some of the 
California fees noted above.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Impact Fees

In gauging the potential for increased revenue in the 
NCTCOG planning area, several sets of estimates must be 
developed under these general classifications:
(1) amount of new development, by land use category, and 
(2) plausible levels of impact fees for each of those 
categories.  Estimates under classification (1) were 
developed here by drawing on a number of sources. Two 
important sets of data derived in this process appear as 
Tables 7 and 8, respectively.  Table 7


-57-

Click HERE for graphic.


-58-	

			TABLE 8

	INFORMATION ON DALLAS/FORT WORTH RETAIL SPACE USE

		                                                      
Shopping Center
		                                                       
Expansion in
	                         Gross Leasable               
Thousand Sq. Ft.
	                        Area in Thousand    Percent            
Planned
	 Section	Square Feet, 1985   Vacant     
1985    1986-87

 1  Dallas CBD	      2,547.5         6.5      67.4      380.7
 2  Dallas Northeast  6,374.9         9.2     290.9      582.5
     Quadrant
 3A Far North Dallas  6,895.5         4.1     299.5      143.5
 3B North Dallas      5,235.0         7.6     161.2      115.4
 3C Dallas, Park      2,922.8         3.7     299.6      621.9
    Cities - OakLawn
 3D Dallas,Love         195.4        11.7      25.0       39.1
    Field-West Dallas  
  4 Dallas, Southeast 1,796.1         6.8      98.7      454.7
    Quadrant  
  5 Dallas, Southwest 5,531.9        11.8     264.8      508.2
    Quadrant 
  6 Addison           1,216.6        16.9      34.8      144.0
  7  Carrollton       2,006.2        22.7     395.1    1,329.8
  8  De Soto/Lancaster1,141.0         3.2     205.0      726.0
  9  Duncanville      1,312.3        11.8     120.8      933.6
 10  Farmers Branch     742.7         9.9      20.1        0.0
 11  Garland          3,964.2        16.6     141.5      579.6
 12  Grand Prairie      861.3         8.3     119.5      537.0
 13  Irving	      4,550.0        10.8     616.0      534.3
 14  Mesquite         4,059.8        10.2     214.7    1,022.4
 15  Richardson       3,824.7        10.3      93.0      271.5
 16  Plano            6,753.8        18.8   1,596.8    1,418.4
 17  Denton/The Colony2,410.7         7.6     477.7      105.0
 18  Lewisville	     ,1,546.2        34.3     431.3    1,258.6
	
     Dallas Total    65,888.4        11.0   5,973.3   11,706.1
	
 19  Arlington        7,613.5        14.1     901.1    2,560.0
 20  Bedford/Euless   1,728.0        21.5     393.1      598.6
 21  Hurst            3,141.2         6.1     448.1      129.8
 22  Fort Worth,      1,152.5         6.4     161.3      829.6
     Northeast Quadrant 
 23  Fort Worth,      2,726.9         9.4     219.2    1,014.2
     Northwest Quadrant 
 24  Fort Worth,      1,112.0         9.8     100.0      272.4
     Southeast Quadrant
 25  Fort Worth,      5,698.9         7.3     769.4	865.4
 26  Fort Worth CBD   1,156.9        16.7       0.0	  0.0
 27  North Richland   2,008.8        16.6     372.0	482.0
     Hills  
			
    Forth Worth Total 26,338.9       11.5   3,364.2    6,752.0
	
    Grand Total       92,227.3       11.2   9,337.5   18,458.1

    Source of data: Sandra Albrecht, 1985 Dallas/Fort Worth 
    Shopping Center Survey, Henry S. Miller Co. Realtors, 
    Dallas, Texas, 1985.


-59-

exhibits estimates of office space in place and recent 
additions to office space, for the Dallas market, while 
Table 8 performs the same functions for retail space.  In 
addition to Tables 7 and 8, information sources included 
the following.  Information on Dallas area industrial 
space wee obtained from the Dallas Chamber of Commerce, 
while information on Fort Worth-Arlington area office, 
commercial and industrial space was obtained from the 
Fort Worth Chamber of Commerce.  Estimates from those 
sources were generally consistent with data on total 
office and industrial space obtained from several other 
sources (including Blacks Office Leasing Guide, The 
Swearingen Co., and the Joe Foster Co.).  Residential 
unit estimates were obtained from a recent NCTCOG 
publication.

Information on the level of impact fees elsewhere, 
developed above, was drawn on to estimate plausible 
levels for the NCTCOG area.  Those estimates consist of 
constant levels of fees, but it must be remembered that 
impact fees should vary within the NCTCOG area, depending 
on location.  Hence, the estimates developed here must be 
viewed as preliminary and subject to considerable 
refinement.  Those estimates are now presented by land 
use category.

Housing Units The estimated construction of housing units 
in 1985 was obtained from COG estimates prepared in March 
1986, (Current Housing, 1986, estimates), which listed 
these additions to the housing stock by area:

		City of Dallas		16,000
		Remainder of Dallas Co.	17,000
		Collin County		4,581
		Denton County		6,780
		Tarrant County		29,381
		Total			73,742


-60-
	
If housing units are charged the following alternative 
levels of impact fees, the corresponding revenue 
alternatives are obtained.

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________

Impact fees on Housing

at $100 per unit              ---	7.4         177	   265
at $250 per unit              ---	18.4        442	   664
at $500 per unit              ---	36.9        885	  1327
at $1000 per unit             ---	73.7       1770	  2655

Nonresidential Space The following estimates of new 
construction in 1985 were developed for each of the major 
land use categories, drawing on Tables 7 and 8,	and on related 
data.
	
       Land Use Category           Million Square Feet
	Office, Dallas County		10
	Total Office, NCTCOG Area	13
	Retail-commercial, NCTCOG area	10
	Industrial, NCTCOG area		15

Estimates of office space expansion were based on data 
obtained from Table 7 and from the Dallas and the Fort 
Worth Chambers of Commerce, including the former's Office 
Space Inventory.  Retail space expansion in 1985 was 9.3 
million square feet (Table 8), so the estimated total of 
10 million square feet for retail-commercial includes 
other forms of commercial use.
		
Rents for industrial space typically average about 
one-fifth those for office space and impact fees are 
scaled accordingly.  (The differences reflect both type 
of construction and location).

In considering the impact fee estimates, the following 
caveats should be noted.  First, the potential for impact 
fees in the next several years will be limited


-61-

because of the current "glut" of space, particularly 
office space, and because the new federal tax law is 
likely to further inhibit new construction.  Second, 
these figures assume all new construction will be charged 
the impact fee at the rates shown.  As noted above, rates 
are liable to vary with location.  Further, fees may be 
limited to areas experiencing considerable growth.  
Currently, the lower value for the impact fee seems more 
likely than the upper level.  However, higher rates 
should be possible in the future.  Subject to those 
caveats, the following estimates are obtained.

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________

Impact Fees on:

Office Space
	
  13 million square feet per year:
   
    per square foot feet, 
        one time charge
    $1 impact fee               ---         13     312   468
    $2 impact fee               ---         26     624	  936
    $5 impact fee               ---         65    1560	 2340

Retail, Commercial Space
	
  10 million square feet per year:
	
  Per square foot fee, 
    one time charge		
  $1 impact fee                ---         10      240	  360
  $2 impact fee                ---         20      480	  720	
  $5 impact fee                ---         50     1200	 1800

Industrial Space

  15 million square feet per year:

     per square foot fee, 
       one time charge
     20˘ impact fee           ---          3      72      108
     $1 impact fee	      ---         15     360	  540


-62-

Sources

Sandra Albrecht, 1985 Dallas/Fort Worth Shopping Center 
Survey, Henry S. Miller Co. Realtors, Dallas, Texas, 1985

Black's Guide Inc., Black's Office Leasing Guide, Fall 
86, Dallas, Texas, 1986.

City of Farmers Branch, Texas, Improvement Ordinances for 
the East Side Improvement District: 
  # 1430 Platting and subdivision of land, Feb. 1983 
  # 1439 Water and sewer line improvements, May, 1983 
  # 1440 Water and sewer line improvements, June, 1983 
  # 1526 Paving improvements, Nov., 1984 
  # 1528 Paving improvements, Nov., 1984

City of Richardson, Texas, Executive Summary of Robert 
Freilich and Martin Leitner on "Financing Transportation 
Improvements Through Impact Fees", Memorandum to Mayor 
and City Council from A. O'Rourke, "Transportation Impact 
Fee Program", Nov. 27, 1983.

City of Richardson, Texas, Draft Ordinance, "Impact Fee 
for Transportation Management Improvements", January 20, 
1986.

Dallas Chamber of Commerce, Industrial Properties Guide, 
1986-87, Dallas, Texas, Aug. 1986.

Dallas Chamber of Commerce, Office Buildings Guide, 
Dallas, Texas, Jan. 1986.

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Current 
Housing 1986 Estimates,
March, 1986.

C. Kenneth Orski, "Suburban Mobility: The Coming 
Transportation Crisis?"
Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 39, No. 2, April 1985, 
283-296.

C. Kenneth Orski, "The Outlook for Urban Transportation", 
in Lester A. Hoel, ed. Innovative Financing for 
Transportation: Practical Solutions and Experiences, U. 
S. Department of Transportation, 1986, 19-38.

David L. Pugh, Christine Bailey Bishop, Charles W. 
Springer, Joanie Carson Raff, A Survey of Capital 
Recovery Fee Systems in Texas, Texas A & M University 
System, 1986.

Gary Reid and Donald Winkler, User Fees Among Cities in 
Los Angeles County and the Rest of Southern California, 
Los Angeles: LA Taxpayers Association, 1986.

William E. Schmidt, New York Times Service, "Development 
Fees Harvest Cash and Protests", Austin 
American-Statesman, Nov. 4, 1985, E1.

Richard Straton, Appendix to this report.

Texas Good Roads Transportation Association and Greater 
San Antonio Chamber of Commerce, Financing the Future: A 
Seminar Exploring Traditional and Innovative 
Transportation Funding Alternatives, San Antonio, Texas, 
Oct. 10, 1985.

Donald Winkler, Comparative Study of Business Taxation by 
Local Government in Southern California, Los Angeles: LA 
Taxpayers Association, 1984.


-63-

Contacts: Mr. James Forte, Director of Finance, City of Plano
	  P.O. Box 830358, Plano, TX 75086 (214) 424-6531

	 Mr. Kelly Walz, Director of Budget and Research
	 City of Farmers Branch, 13000 William Dotson
	 Farmers Branch, TX 75381 (214) 247-3131

	 Swearingen Co., office apace estimates, (214) 922-8700.

Comparison of Estimates of Building Space

Table 7 lists office space totals for the Dallas market 
in early 1986 as 116.5 million square feet, existing, and 
17.8 million square feet, under construction.  Black' a 
Guide for fall, 1986 lists total Dallas-Fort Worth office 
space as 148.1 million square feet.  The Swearingen Co. 
lists essentially the same total for 1986, with this 
breakdown: 

		Dallas Area      - 129.5 million square feet
		Fort Worth Area  - 18.7  million square feet
		Total Metro Area - 148.2 million square feet

The Dallas area figure here seems basically consistent 
with that of Table 7, given completion of much of the 
construction under way earlier in the year. The Joe 
Foster Company lists total industrial space in the Dallas 
Fort-Worth area as 231.9 million square feet, which is 
approximately 1.5 times the total office space figure of 
Black's Guide and the Swearingen Company.  This seems 
roughly consistent with the ratio of new industrial to 
new office space that was estimated in text for the 
NCTCOG area (15 million/l3 million square feet or 1.15), 
which seems reasonable given the presumption that office 
space likely has been expanding somewhat faster than 
industrial space.


-64-

		II. B  BENEFIT ASSESSMENT DISTRICTS
				Detail

General Experience

Benefit assessment districts can be viewed as devices to 
capture some of the benefits of highways which appear in 
the form of increases in private real estate values.  
Robert Schaevitz points out that the use of special 
assessment districts for a number of infrastructure 
investments (local roads, water and sewer improvements) 
is not new, and is sanctioned by law in a number of 
states.  In most cases, the key point is the existence of 
demonstrable improvement of specific properties, implying 
a special implying a special rather then a general 
benefit.  When the benefit conferred is not universally 
or equally shared by all properties within the given 
political jurisdiction, charging for the improvements is 
termed an assessment; when the benefit is more-or-less 
universally and equally shared, charging for the 
improvement is termed a tax.  Often, simple formulas have 
been used to estimate the amount of benefits derived such 
as charges based on square feet or front feet of a 
development.  However, in many states, charges must be 
based on more precise estimates of benefits conferred, 
and further, can be independent of the costs of the 
improvement.  A critical concern in establishing a 
benefit a benefit assessment district, then is a good 
faith effort to establish a formula measuring benefits in 
a understandable, fair and consistent manner.  The use of 
benefit assessment districts is often attractive to 
policy makers because it isolates potential opposition 
and makes use of the principle that the primary 
beneficiaries of public investment pay for at least a 
share of the benefits they have received.

Benefit assessment districts are often used to help 
finance downtown improvement, based on experience in 
Denver, Louisville, Minneapolis and


-65-

Portland, Oregon.  They have been tied to rail transit 
benefits in Los Angeles, Atlanta and Miami.   There have 
also been attempts to account for highway benefits in the 
Denver area, Albuquerque and Santa Fe.

Los Angeles is creating special benefit assessment 
districts around each of 17 stations on its planned rail 
transit line.  Private assessments will cover 5 percent 
of the capital cost of the project.  The southern 
California Regional Transit District will charge 30  per 
square foot of space per year for buildings within each 
district.  Office space rental in Central Los Angeles 
runs about $25 per square foot, so the assessment is 
about one percent of rental value.

Downtown Denver’s benefit assessment district charges 
properties an annual fee involving a sliding scale based 
on distance from the central transitway-pedestrian mall, 
which covers a 14 block area in the center of Denver.  
Originally the district was established for the area 
between 15th and 17th streets along the length of the 
mall, and then 1984, its coverage was expanded to embrace 
the area from 14th to 19th streets.  Thus, a large 
portion of the CBD is included.

In Colorado, landowners are allowed to form taxing 
districts for the purpose of financing road construction 
on their land.  In the Denver area, several of those 
districts have formed the Joint Southeast Public 
Improvement District to undertake a $20 million privately 
funded program of highway improvements.

In Santa Fe, New Mexico, a benefit assessment district to 
account for parking improvement in the downtown areas has 
been the subject of detailed planning studies.  Serious 
consideration is also being given to a benefit assessment 
district to cover the costs of a new loop road and 
additional freeway ramps in a major commercial 
development center in Albuquerque.  In the latter case, 
it was


-66-

estimated that all of the costs could be assigned to 
property owners in the center with considerable benefits 
left over.  In the former case, the proposed charges to 
property owners amounted to approximately 5 percent of 
current rents.  Further, all of the required assessments 
were below the cost of a parking apace (calculated as 
$6,000 in capital coats, which was treated as equivalent 
to $753 per year, in turn implying an interest rate of 
about 12%.)

Local Applications of Benefit Assessment Districts 
Benefit assessment districts in Texas are subsumed under 
the general heading of Public Improvement Districts 
(PIDs) which are authorized in the state by the Public 
Improvement District Assessment Act, Article 126j-4.12 of 
Vernon's Annotated Texas Statutes, originally passed in 
1977 and amended in 1983.  The use of PIDs in Dallas was 
initially entertained by the City Council in January, 
1983.  On April 2, 1983, the voters of Dallas approved 
the use of PIDa as an appropriate mechanism to fund 
special improvements.  Dallas has not yet established any 
PID, but several requests are pending.

The Fort Worth City Council has approved a downtown tax 
assessment district covering a 140 block area.  Funds 
will be used for sidewalk and street maintenance, 
landscaping, promotion, transportation, security, parking 
and management.  The first year's budget is $742,000 
(Dallas Morning News, 7/23/86.)   

In Texas highway finance, Road Utility Districts (RUDs) 
and County Road Districts (CRDs) can be viewed as 
variants under the heading of Benefit
Assessment District.  Both collect revenue from 
beneficiaries of road construction within a well-defined 
district to pay for that road construction.  To create a 
RUD, a petition must be signed by 100 percent of the 
landowners within a proposed district; the petition is 
submitted to the Highway Commission, which then creates 
the RUD.  The RUD can acquire, construct and improve 
roads,


-67-

and pay for that activity by special fees assessed by the 
district, or it may issue bonds to be paid for by levying 
an ad valorem tax.  A CRD works within the framework of 
the County government.  The County Commissioners' Court 
legislates the area to be included and serves as its 
governing body. It issues bonds to pay for the building 
of roads and pays for them by an ad valorem tax on all 
taxable property within the district (Bahar Norris, "Road 
Utility Districts", North Central Texas COG, June 3, 
1986.)

The RUD and CRD can be viewed as benefit assessment 
districts because they pay for the special benefits 
accruing to the members of their district. However, they 
differ somewhat from the cases described above because 
they levy taxes as well as assessments (in the case of 
RUDs), which could be viewed as merely a question of 
semantics.  In addition, RUDs are voluntary associations.  
Hence, it could be argued there is some overlap of 
categories: RUDs and CRDs can be viewed as classifiable 
under both benefit assessment districts and property 
taxes; RUDs can also fit under the heading of Developer 
Contributions Through Negotiations.  As indicated 
earlier, there are a great many financing mechanisms, and 
consequently, classification systems for them will not be 
watertight.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Benefit Assessment Districts

Benefit Assessment Districts typically collect revenue 
from existing as well as new construction in high growth 
areas, with growth presumably related to improved 
transportation facilities.  That structure of assessments 
is assumed in the following calculations.

Office rental value asking prices in the central business 
district of the city of Dallas are about the same level 
as those in Los Angeles, at $25 per square foot, while 
outlying area asking price rentals range from about a 
third to a


-68-
half of the CBD levels ($8 to $12).  However, because of 
the current "glut" of space, actual rentals, accounting 
for concessions, are at a much lower rate.  Currently, 
15˘ per square feet per year might be "most reasonable" 
for CBD benefit assessment, applying the Los Angeles 
ratio of assessment to rent.  However, a somewhat higher 
ratio can be expected in the future as the glut of floor 
space is dissipated; further, a higher ratio is also 
possible, as in the Santa Fe case (5% was the ratio 
derived there).

Two cases can be considered, drawing on the data of 
tables 7 and 8:

(1)  Benefit assessment districts limited to the Dallas 
CBD at 20˘ per square foot, applied to 40 million 
square feet of office space, existing or under 
construction, and to 2.5 million square feet of 
commercial space.

(2)  Benefit assessment districts for high growth areas 
other than the Dallas CBD, including the North 
Central Expressway Corridor, the LBJ Corridor, and 
the Las Colinas and Mid-Cities-high growth areas, at 
10˘ per square foot, applied to approximately 70 
million square feet of office space, existing or 
under construction, and to 45 million square feet of 
commercial space.

Revenues obtained under those cases are as follows:
______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________

Benefit Assessment Districts

(1) Dallas CBD	                ---      8.5    204	306
(2) Other high growth areas	---     11.5    276	414
		   
			Total	        20.0    480	720


-69-

Sources

City of Denver, Colorado, Documents on 16th Street Mall:
    Ordinance #575, Series of 1983, Creation of District 
       for 16th Street  Pedestrian and Transit Mall.
    Ordinance # 736, Series of 1983, Assessing annual 
       costs of Mall
    Ordinance # 662, Series of 1984, Assessing annual 
       costs of Mall
    Amendatory Cooperation Agreement, 1984, with 
        "Downtown Denver, Inc. (DDI)"
    Proposed Contract, Continuing operation of Mall, with 
        DDI, March 6, 1986.

City of San Diego, "Facilities Benefits 
Assessments-Growth Management Implementation".

City of San Diego, "Ordinance Relating to the Designation 
of Areas of Benefit to be Assessed to Cost of Public 
Facilities." Ordinance 0-15318.

"Fort Worth OKs Tax District to Spruce Up Downtown Area", 
Dallas Morning News, 7/23/86, p. 19A.

Lawrence D. Goldstein, "A Local Share Financing Strategy 
for the Downtown Seattle Transportation Project", in 
Lester A. Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for 
Transportation, U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT), 
1986, 255-290.

Renee Perkins Jaynes and Michael Levinson "An Issue Paper 
on the Use of Public Improvement Districts in Dallas" 
City Manager's Office, City of Dallas, January 13, 1986.

Bahar Norris, "Road Utility Districts", Memorandum to 
Gordon A. Shunk, North Central Texas Council of 
Governments, June 3, 1986.

C. Kenneth Orski, "Suburban Mobility: The Coming 
Transportation Crisis?" Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 
39, No. 2, April 1985, 283-296.

C. Kenneth Orski, "The Outlook for Urban Transportation 
in Lester A. Hoel, ed. Innovative Financing for 
Transportation, U.S. DOT, 1986, 19-38.

Marc Samet, "Financing and Implementing Special 
Assessments", Dade County, Florida, 1984.

Robert C. Schaevitz, "Viability of Wide Area Assessment 
Districts for Financing Street Highway and Parking 
Improvements", in Lester A. Hoel, ed., Innovative 
Financing for Transportation, U.S. DOT, 1986, 173-196.

Southern California Rapid Transit District, Benefit 
Assessment Report (Preliminary), Metro Rail Benefit 
Assessment Districts.

Texas Good Roads Transportation Association and Greater 
San Antonio Chamber of Commerce, Financing the Future: A 
Seminar Exploring Traditional and Innovative 
Transportation Funding Alternatives, San Antonio, Texas, 
Oct. 10, 1985.


-70-

Calculations

In calculating potential square feet for benefit 
assessment districts in the NCTCOG area, the following 
sources were employed:

(1) For Dallas CBD, Office Space: Table 7, "existing" 
plus "under construction" in million square feet: 37.658 
+ 6.394 = 40.052.  For Dallas CBD, commercial space: 
Table 8, "Gross Leasable Area" + "Expansion, 1985": 2.548 
+ .067 = 2.615, rounded to 2.5. 

(2) Other than Dallas CBD, Office Space: Table 7, retail 
space, Table 8. "High growth areas" were approximated by 
selection of specific sections in Tables 7 and 8, as 
follows:

	Other than Dallas CBD, office space, Table 7.
 			million square feet

					   Under
     Section	            Existing     Construction    Total

 3. No. Central	            9.054	   1.678        10.732
 4. LBJ Corridor	   18.370	   2.514        20.884
 7. Far N. Dallas	   10.495	   1.605        12.100
 8. Far No. Central	    7.020	   1.194         8.214
11. Las Colinas	           10.980	   0.933        11.915
12. Mid Cities	            4.338	   0.743         5.081
	
	Total	           60.257	   8.669        68.926

	Other than Dallas CBD, retail space, Table 8.

		           Gross	  Expansion
  Section	        Leasable area      In 1985	Total
	
3A. Far N. Dallas	   6.896	   0.300	7.196
 6. Addison	           1.216	   0.035	1.251
 7. Carrollton	           2.006	   0.395	2.401
10. Farmers Branch         0.743           0.020	0.763
11. Garland                3.964           0.142	4.106
13. Irving	           4.550           0.616	5.166
15. Richardson	           3.825	   0.093	3.918
16. Plano	           6.754           1.597	8.351
19. Arlington	           7.614           0.901	8.515
21. Hurst	           3.141           0.448	3.589
			
    Total	          40.709	   4.547       45.256

    The total was rounded to 45 million square feet.  
    Admittedly, there is an arbitrary element in the 
    selection process here.  However, there should be 
    some balancing of omitted high growth areas with 
    subareas of the included sections that are not high 
    growth areas.


-71-

   II.C LEASING OR SALE OF DEVELOPMENT RIGHTS OR AIR RIGHTS
			Detail

Transportation agencies may lease or sell development 
rights for the apace above, below or adjacent to their 
land holdings and facilities.  Such space can be viewed 
as a form of land, and the rights can be priced 
accordingly. (Land typically accounts for about 20 to 25 
percent of real estate value.)

Johnson and Hoel note that eminent domain powers are 
frequently used to assemble land for transportation 
projects and that several court cases have questioned 
whether those powers allow public agencies to obtain air 
(and subsurface) rights in excess of those needed to 
achieve the objectives for which the land was condemned.  
They also note that citizen groups often contend that the 
public does not gain sufficient benefits from the lease 
or sale of development rights.

Some recent examples may be noted.  Air rights over 
Denver to Civic Center Transit District were leased in 
1981, and the lease is expected to provide $55 million 
during its first 15 years. In Miami, air rights over a 
transit station were leased in exchange for the 
acquisition of a site for the station plus 4 percent of 
unadjusted gross income for each year of the lease, 
expected to equal $2 to $3 million a year.  The air 
rights development is expected to consist of 600,000 
square feet of office space, 50,000 square feet of retail 
space, and a 300 room hotel.

Lawrence Goldstein estimates that in Seattle, the sale of 
development rights could capture as much as 30 percent of 
the $130 million in new property value projected to be 
created by major improvements to the regional bus system.


-72-
Potential for Increased Revenue, Sale of Development 
Rights

Consider the case of State Highway 190.  In Richardson 
and Plano, zoning for office and retail space along SH 
190 may total 70 million square feet; however, only part 
of that land is expected to be developed, so actually 
developed building space then is estimated as 20 million 
square feet.  (Estimate by J. Michael Chism, Richardson 
Chamber of Commerce.)  The "land" component per square 
foot can be estimated as approximately $30 to $40 per 
square foot, with an increment due to the highway 
construction of $10 to $15 per square foot.  Given the 
financial experience of the Miami and Seattle projects, 
and the ratio of the sale of development rights to market 
value, noted above, it seems reasonable to charge a 
development fee of $5 per square foot.  This will yield 
total revenue of $100 million.

The prospective Richardson-Plano development is only part 
of the likely SH 190 induced development, in turn only 
part of all induced development because of new highways.  
Hence, a total of $500 million over the 24 period seems a 
modest estimate of total potential revenues.  An annual 
figure of $20 million corresponds to the 500 million 
total.  In tabular form, this result is exhibited as 
follows:

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________                                  Current         

Sale of Development Rights    ---      20        500        750


-73-

Sources

Lawrence D. Goldstein, " A Local Share Financing Strategy 
for the Downtown Seattle Transportation Project", in 
Lester A. Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for 
Transportation, U.S. DOT, 1986, 255-290.

Garry T. Johnson and Lester A. Hoel "Innovative Financing 
for Transportation What are the Options?"  in Lester A. 
Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for Transportation, U.S. 
DOT 1986 1-19’ See p. 7 in particular.

"Richardson Grapples with 190 Zoning", Plano Star-Courier, 
Aug. 24, 1986, p.1.

Rice Center, Houston, Texas, A Guide to Innovative 
Financing Mechanisms for Mass Transportation - An Update, 
Prepared for Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D.C., Dec., 1985.

"Planners Put Hunt Request on Hold", Richardson Daily 
News, Aug. 20, 1986,p.1.

Contact: J. Michael Chism
         Director of Economic Development
         Richardson Chamber of Commerce
         214-234-4141


-74-

	II.D DEVELOPER CONTRIBUTIONS THROUGH NEGOTIATIONS 
				Detail

General Experience

There are a variety of negotiated developer 
contributions to highway development including land 
donations, monetary donations and ad hoc arrangements of 
developer contributions to highway construction.  Orski 
concludes that because of statutory ant judicial 
restraints placed on development fees and assessments, 
many jurisdictions become involved in ad hoc negotiations 
with individual developers to secure private 
participation in transportation financing.  He sees local 
governments as becoming adept at bargaining with 
developers.  William Garrison cautions on this point, 
arguing that developers are liable to be more experienced 
and sophisticated in the negotiation process than are 
public officials, so that the developers will often get a 
better than "fair" deal, and the public will be the 
loser. Local governments can bargain by using devices 
involving discretionary development approvals such as 
subdivision approvals, rezoning, density bonuses, reduced 
parking requirements, etc. These can be viewed as a 
variant of the argument "why not buy and sell 
zoning...legally, that is?", as suggested by Marion 
Clawson some years ago.

Johnson and Hoel note cases of donations of land and 
money to transportation projects, including a $9 million 
dollar campaign to save the cable cars in San Francisco.  
They point out that transportation agencies must be 
legally empowered to accept donations, and that 
establishment of a non-profit tax exempt committee to 
accept donations can be useful for tax purposes.  Such 
contributions can be invested without tax liability and 
corporations making contributions are eligible to receive 
tax write-offs.  Orski cites a number of successful cases 
of developer contributions through negotiations.  Several


-75-

California cases are noted, including an Irvine Company 
contribution of $60 million to pay for local 
transportation improvements in its 480 acre Irvine 
Center; a contribution of $57.5 million worth of arterial 
roads, freeway overpasses and interchanges and other 
facilities in the one-billion dollar Rancho Carmel mixed 
use development; and an $80 million pledged contribution 
for transportation improvements around Hacienda Business 
Park in Alameda County, California.  Finally, several 
large developers, including Friendswood Development 
Company and Mitchell Energy and Development Corporation 
have helped pay for the financing of road improvements in 
the Houston area.

Local Experience

Transportation Corporations can legally be organized in 
Texas, and Texas Transportation Corporations can enter 
into contracts with government agencies to construct or 
improve highway projects and to sell completed projects 
to the Highway Commission (Bahar Norris memorandum on 
Transportation Corporations, North Central Texas COG, 
June 3, 1986).  There have been a number of land 
donations, prospective land donations and attempted land 
donations in the NCTCOG planning area, but often the 
attempts have not come to fruition.  For example, Trammel 
Crow, John Stemmons and Ben Carpenter, leading area 
developers, have offered to donate land and contribute to 
the financing of a 23-mile light rail line linking Dallas 
with the Dallas-Fort Worth airport and spanning major 
land holdings of the three developers (Orski, 1985). H. 
Ross Perot, Jr. and Nelson Bunker Hunt have volunteered 
to respectively contribute 250 and 107 acres for a North 
Fort Worth Freeway which would improve access to their 
properties (Fort Worth Star Telegram, 7/123/86, p.l, 4. 
and Dallas Times Herald, 7/10/86).  However, the securing 
of land donations for North Central Expressway widening 
and for State Highway 360 have generally been 
disappointing, to date, although


-76-

some donations have been obtained.  (Dallas Morning News, 
2/27/86, 1A and 5/30/86, 21A on North Central Expressway, 
and Arlington Citizen Journal, 7/13/86; Fort Worth Star 
Telegram, 7/11/86, p. 13; and Dallas Times Herald 
8/13/86, p. 1, on State Highway 360).

Potential for Increased Revenue, Ad Hoc Negotiations

Because of the variety of devices that can be involved in 
ad hoc negotiations, revenue estimates must be 
speculative.  However, it seems reasonable that revenue 
raised should be at least on the order of that obtained 
from the sale of development rights, yielding the 
following:


______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________ 				                                Revenue in 

	
Ad Hoc Negotiations             ---     20      500        750

Sources

City of Escondido, "Ground Lease Development Rights", 
January 1, 1981.

Marion Clawson, "Why Not Sell Zoning and Rezoning? 
(legally, that is)," Cry California, Winter, 1966-67, pp. 
9, 39.

Gary T. Johnson and Lester A. Hoel "Innovative Financing 
for Transportation: What are the Options?" in Lester A. 
Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for Transportation, 1986, 
p. 8 in particular.

Bahar Norris, "The Highway Commission's Updates on the 
Texas Transportation Corporation Act", Memorandum to 
Gordon A. Shunk, NCTCOG, June 3, 1986.

C. Kenneth Orski " Suburban Mobility: The Coming 
Transportation Crisis?", Transportation Quarterly, April 
1985, pp. 291-293 in particular.

Rice Center, Houston, Texas, A Guide to Innovative 
Financing Mechanisms for Mass Transportation - An Update, 
Prepared for Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D. C., Dec., 1985.


-77-

		III. PARKING FEES, FINES AND TAXES
			     Overview
Definition

Revenue obtained from local government taxing of 
commercial parking lots and from traffic tickets and 
parking meters.

Examples

New York City, San Francisco

Financial Results

Revenues from parking charges collected from private 
parking operators has yielded $12 million annually on a 6 
percent tax in New York City and $5.5 million per year on 
a 25 percent tax in San Francisco.  Revenues from parking 
stickers, meters, permits and citations also may be 
substantial in urban areas.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative It has been estimated that 
   Dallas could obtain revenues from parking tickets 
   of $8.9 million and revenue from parking meters of 
   $3.4 million in 1990 by better enforcement and 
   management.  For parking tickets, there appear to 
   be no legal problems as long as additional parking 
   tickets are not due to selective enforcement.

   Political Opposition from businesses not 
   conveniently accessible by mass transit would be 
   expected as well as from the owners of parking 
   lots.  Most individuals would probably be only 
   marginally affected and therefore might not object 
   to the tax.

   Economic There is potential for a new and stable 
   revenue source from the taxation of commercial 
   parking lots.  The tax is a user fee and therefore 
   fairly efficient.  There is an equity question 
   raised over taxing only commercial lots rather than 
   all long term parking in an area.  There are 
   indications that traffic patterns may be 
   significantly affected by the taxation of parking 
   lots or increased enforcement of parking meters 
   with an increased incentive to use mass transit.  
   Additionally the higher fees may encourage shopping 
   in areas without taxation, that is, suburban 
   shopping areas. Central city governments (Dallas 
   and Fort Worth) are likely to entertain this 
   hypothesis and consequently, will be reluctant to 
   impose higher costs on parking.


-78-

		III. PARKING FEES, FINES AND TAXES
				Detail
General Information

Revenue sources from parking include:

1. Parking fees
	a. from meters
	b. from municipal lots and garages
2. Fines for parking violations
3. Taxes on Parking Lot operations

Almost all parking revenue in the Dallas-Fort Worth area 
is collected in the Central Business Districts of Dallas and 
Fort Worth.  There is some evidence suggesting a potential for 
increased revenue from parking, but there also
appears to be reluctance on the part of central city 
administrations to fully capitalize on that potential, 
probably because of a sense that this could drive 
business activity from the central cities to the suburbs.

Currently, annual revenue from meters is approximately 
$1.0 million per year in the City of Dallas, with the 
bulk of revenue obtained from meters in the Central 
Business District (CBD).  An increase in meter rates in 
the summer of 1986 increased revenue about 20 percent.  
Further increases can occur by way of higher rates and 
increased metering.  Given the 1986 increase in rates, it 
is unlikely that further increases will occur for at 
least a year or two after that date, and perhaps not for 
several years.  CBD rates now are almost all $1 per hour.  
There is some potential for metering in other sections of 
the city, including the Greenville Avenue district, but 
this too appears relatively modest.  The current annual 
revenue from meters in Fort Worth is $0.7 million per 
year, but the potential for expansion seems even more 
limited than is the


-79-

case in Dallas.  (Information from respective 
transportation departments of cities of Dallas and Fort 
Worth.)

In Dallas, municipal ownership of garages and lots 
consist only of garages at City Hall, the Public Library 
and the Convention Center and of lots at Love Field.  
These parking facilities are not under centralized 
management but each is run by a separate agency of the 
city government.

A recent study carried out for the City of Dallas by 
Brophy and Associates, a consulting firm, concluded that 
the city could increase its parking revenues by nearly 
$10 million a year if it wrote more parking tickets and 
more fully enforced collection of parking fines (Dallas 
Morning News, June 18, 1986).  The study concluded that 
both parking meter revenue and parking violations 
collected were "low".  The study estimated that revenue 
from meter operations could increase from $0.8 million in 
1985 to $3.4 million in 1990.  (The level of meter 
revenue in 1986 is at roughly an $0.96 million annual 
rate, the 20 percent increase over 1985 presumably 
accounted for by the increase in rates noted earlier.)  
The study also estimated that greater diligence in 
issuing parking citations and in collecting fines would 
increase fines collected from $1.5 million in 1985 to 
$8.9 million in 1990. The study recommended increased 
enforcement against parking violations by towing vehicles 
and by use of the "Denver Boot", which clamps onto a 
vehicle wheel and immobilizes it until overdue tickets 
are paid.  However, some city council members and Tommy 
Jones, Manager of the city's parking meter operations, 
are doubtful that enforcement will be increased.

Gary Johnson and Lester Hoel argue that the taxing of 
commercial parking lots shows great promise, both for 
revenue and for causing some shift to transit from 
automobiles.  A six per cent tax on commercial parking in 
New York City yields


 -80-

approximately $12 million per year, and a 2 percent tax 
on commercial parking in San Francisco generates 
approximately $5.5 million annually.  Both New York and 
San Francisco are more densely populated and probably 
more congested than Dallas-Fort-Worth, and so can 
probably charge more for parking; on the other hand, a 
greater number of auto trips to the CBD may well occur in 
Dallas-Fort Worth, so the revenue potential could be 
comparable.

Johnson and Hoel do recognize that increases in parking 
prices, by way of taxes, can alter travel patterns.  In 
particular, this can discourage downtown shopping and 
job-seeking, speaking up the movement of economic 
activity to the suburbs.  This may be the key source of 
apparent central city reluctance to aggressively tap the 
revenue potential of parking charges.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Parking Fees, Fines and 
Taxes Minimum Estimate  From information cited above, 
current revenue from parking meters is bout $1.7 million 
per year for Dallas and Fort Worth, combined, while 
revenue from parking fines appears to be about $2.5 
million per year.

The Dallas City Council approved spending $432,000 for 
3,000 new parking meters installed in 1986, and it is 
estimated that within the next several years the minimum 
increase from more meters and higher parking rates will 
be roughly $0.5 million per year.  If that limited 
increase is treated as the only change, the following 
minimum revenue increases are projected.

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________ 				                                Revenue in 

Parking meters and fines       4.2        ---     ---    ---
Meter revenue only             ---        0.5      12     18


-81-

Maximum Estimates  If Dallas-Fort Worth revenue from 
parking lot taxes were of roughly the same magnitude as 
that of San Francisco and New York, approximately $10 
million in additional revenue would be raised.  In 
addition if meter and parking fine revenue were raised to 
the level predicted by Brophy and Associates, cited 
above, the gain for Dallas would be roughly $10 million 
per year.  If Fort-Worth had a corresponding gain of $5 
million per year in its meter and parking revenue, the 
area increment would be $15 million per year.  These 
changes imply the following revenue projections.

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________
                                        
Maximum revenue parking fees and fines

Parking lot taxes              ---      10      240        360
Parking meters and             ---      15      360        540
parking fines

Total                                   25     600     900

Sources

Gary T. Johnson and Lester A.Hoel, Innovative Financing 
for Transportation: What are the Options? in Lester 
A.Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for Transportation: 
Practical Solutions and Experiences.  Office of U.S. 
Secretary of Transportation, Washington, D.C., April 
1986, DOT-1-86-20.

"Study Lists ways to Reap Millions From Parking", Dallas 
Morning News, June 18, 1986.

Information on city parking meter revenues obtained from 
respective transportation department of cities of Dallas 
Fort Worth.

Contacts:  Tommy Jones, Manager of City of Dallas parking 
           meter operations  214-670-3772.

           Martha Lundy, City of Fort Worth Transportation 
           Department,  817-870-7804


-82-

		IV. LOCAL OPTION MOTOR FUEL TAXES
				Overview
Definition

A local option motor fuel tax is a tax levied by local 
jurisdictions for local purposes and is collected in 
addition to state and federal motor fuel taxes.

Examples

Florida; Nevada; Albuquerque, New Mexico; Virginia

Financial Results

Significant revenues can be obtained, varying according 
to tax rates and travel patterns.

In Florida, Dade County has a 6˘ local option gasoline 
tax, while Lafayette County has a 4˘ local option 
gasoline tax.  In 1985, however, each received about $26 
per capita from their respective taxes.  (The Dade County 
receipts were $45 million, the population was 1.7 
million, and per capita returns were $26.4.  The 
Lafayette County receipts were $112,000 and population 
was 4.3 thousand, so per capita returns were $26.0.)  
Local option gasoline taxes are 4˘ per gallon in Nevada, 
and 2˘ per gallon in Albuquerque, New Mexico and four 
counties in Virginia.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative State-enabling legislation is 
   required for local jurisdictions to levy local option 
   motor fuel taxes.  Restrictions are often imposed on the 
   localities as to the use of the revenues, the rates that 
   may be imposed, and the procedure for local approval of 
   the tax.  In Texas, it is possible that revenues 
   collected would have to be distributed in the same 
   fashion as state motor fuel tax revenue, with 
   approximately three-fourths to transportation and 
   one-fourth to education.

   Political It is always difficult to implement a new tax. 
   The need for revenue must be understood by the community 
   and the existing tax structure must not be too high.  To 
   this extent, any potential local tax must be considered 
   along with existing state and federal taxes.  
   Difficulties may be particularly pronounced in Texas 
   where there is significant opposition from the State 
   Comptroller's Office and little support from the 
   counties.  The local option tax should be popular in 
   localities which have significant traffic from 
   nonresidents to whom the tax may be passed.  

   Economic It is a fairly good tax in that it is a user 
   fee.  It is not a 100 percent benefit charge, however, 
   since nonusers of the highway also benefit to the extent 
   that community services are provided more efficiently, 
   e.g., fire and police services.


-83-

		IV. LOCAL OPTION MOTOR FUEL TAX
				Detail

General Information

State motor fuel tax rates are exhibited in Table 9 which 
also lists the 13 states having local motor fuel taxes.  
Most of those states are located in the Southeast (5) and 
Far West (4) regions of the country.  Specific examples 
of local option taxes include both excise taxes (per 
gallon taxation) and sales taxes (a percentage tax on the 
amount of gasoline sales). Some examples of excise taxes 
are:

	Hawaii     - county tax of 4 to 6.5 cents per gallon
	Florida    - county tax ranging from 2 to 6 cents 
                     per gallon; additional local taxes are 
                     permitted.
	Nevada     - Reno and Las Vegas: 2 cents per gallon
	New Mexico - Bernalillo County (Albuquerque): 2 
                     cents per gallon
	Virginia   - Four county: 2 cents per gallon

Some examples of local sales taxes on gasoline are:

	California - in addition to a state gasoline sales 
                     tax of 4.75%, local governments assess 
                     1.25%, except for Bay Area governments
                     which assess 1.75%
	New York   - the state assesses 4% and, in addition, 
                     local governments  assess from 1% to 4%.

The California and New York sales taxes on motor fuel are 
in addition to the state excise taxes on motor fuel.

Case Example - Florida

Florida has four different types of local option fuel 
taxes available although only two are currently in use.  
The first tax, approved by the state legislature in the 
early 1970s, was the Voted Gas Tax.  This tax allows a 1˘ 
per gallon tax to be levied subject to voter approval in 
a county-wide referendum.


-84-

[GRAPHIC] /fnc14.gif>HERE for graphic.

-85-

The second and most widely used option is the Local 
Option Gas Tax.  This option allows a tax of up to 6˘ (in 
whole pennies) to be placed on a gallon of gasoline.  
This tax may be implemented by a vote of the county's 
governing body and does not require a voter referendum.  
The tax may be in addition to the Voted Gas Tax 
(therefore allowing up to a total of 7˘) or may be levied 
separately.

The third available tax is the Metropolitan 
Transportation Authority Tax. This tax requires a 
population in excess of 200,000 people with a 
metropolitan planning organization eligible to receive 
W-36 federal urban funds.  In addition, the area must 
have levied the full 6˘ of the Local Option Gas Tax.  An 
area that meets these conditions is eligible to place up 
to 4˘ of additional tax on a gallon of gasoline if 
approved by referendum. This tax has not been utilized as 
yet but about 10 areas in Florida comprising 16 counties 
are potentially eligible, though not all have the full 6˘ 
Local Option Gas Tax in place.  This tax was defeated in 
one 3-county area by a 4-1 margin.  The suggested reason 
for this defeat, however, was its linkage on the same 
referendum with an increase in the property tax.  In 
addition, it is always difficult to tax by referendum.

The fourth tax is the Local Option Sales Tax which is a 1 
percent tax that can only be used for fixed guideway 
transit systems or for buses connected with the system.  
It was originally passed by the state legislature for a 
metrorail system in Dade County, but it failed there in a 
referendum.  Five other counties are currently eligible 
to have referendums on this tax, but none have passed it 
as yet.

Of the 67 counties in Florida in 1986, 48 employ the 
Local Option Gas Tax. Of these, 10 use both the Local 
Option Gas Tax and the Voted Gas Tax. Two other


-86-

counties use only the Voted Gas Tax. The amount of the 
Local Option Gas Tax imposed by counties was as follows 
in summer, 1986: Number of Counties Amount of Tax

		15................6˘
		29................4˘
 		1.................3˘
 		3.................2˘

The number will probably change annually, as counties 
can implement the Local Option Gas Tax every September 
1.  All proceeds of the local option gas tax are 
bondable and may be used for both highway and 
transit-related items. Categories that are specifically 
eligible include:

- Public transportation operation and maintenance
- Road and right-of-way maintenance and equipment
- Road and right-of-way drainage
- Street lighting
- Traffic signs, engineering, signalization, and 
  pavement markings
- Bridge maintenance and operation
- Debt service and current expenditures for capital 
  projects in the above areas, including construction and 
  reconstruction of roads.

In general, the Local Option Gas Tax is unrestricted for 
transportation use.

The Local Option Gas Tax is collected by the state at the 
retail level.  The state charges a 6 percent collection 
fee and retailers are paid 1-3 percent, depending on the 
amount collected.  There are some rebates to certain 
entities such as non-profit organizations.  It is 
estimated that counties receive from 91 to 92 percent of 
the gross revenue collected.  The Voted Gas Tax, in 
contrast, has no state charge or rebates.

The Local Option Gas Tax was collected at the wholesale 
level until it was changed to the retail level in January 
1986.  The primary reason was the


-87-

potential for fraud at the wholesale level since 
distributors may indicate that fuel is being sent to 
non-tax counties when in fact its final destination is 
taxed counties.  The retail level collection avoids this 
problem, but generates problems of its own.  The major 
problem at this level is that gasoline retailers are one 
of the most delinquent groups of taxpayers, with many 
going out of business before paying the tax.  In 
addition, the retail level entails collecting at many 
more points than at the wholesale level.

Revenues from the local option motor fuel taxes vary 
markedly depending on population and traffic patterns.  
Dade County, which includes Miami, and has the largest 
population of all counties in the state, grosses roughly 
$7.5 million for each 1˘ tax that it levies on gasoline.  
The county has the maximum 6˘ Local Option Gas Tax but 
not the Voted Gas Tax.  In contrast, one of the least 
populated counties, Lafayette County, grosses about 
$28,000 for each 1˘ levied.  That county has 4˘ of the 
Local Optional Gas Tax in effect. Both Dade and Lafayette 
counties annually receive about $26 per capita from their 
local option gasoline taxes although the Dade tax is 6˘ 
per gallon in contrast to the Lafayette tax of 4˘ per 
gallon.  This can be explained by a much larger 
proportion of out-of-county customers in Lafayette 
County.

New legislation passed in 1985 creates an incentive for 
localities to enact all 6˘ of the Local Option Gas Tax.  
If the maximum tax is imposed, then any or all of the 
proceeds can be used as matching funds with the state for 
projects that involve construction of the state highway 
system.  State matching funds are set at 20 percent of 
the project.  It is hoped that localities levying the 
full 6˘ will become less reliant on state revenues.

In enacting local option fuel taxes it must be stressed 
that the overall level of taxation on fuel must be taken 
into account. Both federal and state taxes


-88-

must be considered.  Consumers do not look at individual 
tax levels when determining how much fuel to purchase and 
where to purchase it, but at the total price of fuel.  
Thus, in deciding the amount of a local motor fuel tax to 
place on motor fuel in a particular locality, the federal 
tax of 9  a gallon and Florida’s state tax of 9.7  a 
gallon must be considered.  Furthermore, surrounding 
localities’ tax structures must also e taken into account 
since lower prices in neighboring communities may well 
reduce the revenue generated by increasing a local tax on 
fuel.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Local Option Fuel Taxes
Approximately 2 billion gallons of motor fuel are sold 
annually in the NCTCOG planning area; with state fuel 
taxes as of 1986 at 10 cents per gallon, state motor fuel 
tax collections currently amount to approximately $200 
million from the local area.  (The 1987 increase of  
state fuel taxes to 15 cents per gallon should then yield 
approximately $300 million from the local area.)  Local 
options taxes can be calculated, based on a cents per 
gallon charge paralleling excise taxes currently in force 
in other localities, or based on a percentage tax 
paralleling percentage sales taxes now in force in 
California and New York.  Revenue obtainable locally is 
shown for several alternatives, as follows.


-89-

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________
                                        
 Motor Fuel Taxes

($200 million collected       (200)     ---      ---      ---
 by state in 1986  
 at 10˘ per gallon.)
	
A. Local Excise Tax             0       ---      ---      ---
- Local option gasoline tax    ---      20       480	  720
  at 1˘ per gallon
- Local option gasoline tax    ---      40       960	 1440
  at 2˘ per gallon
- Local option gasoline tax    ---      80      1920 	 2880
  at 4˘ per gallon 
- Local option gasoline tax    ---     200      4800	 7200
  at 10˘ per gallon  

B. Sales Taxes - specifically 
   on gasoline

Approximately 2 billion gals. 
 sold currently
If $0.75 per gallon, $1.5 
 billion in sales

      - at 1% tax             ---       15        360	  540
      - at 4% tax             ---       60       1440	 2160

The figures shown cover taxes collected.  In practice, 
motor fuel tax revenues currently are distributed as 
approximately three-fourths to highway transportation and 
one-fourth to education.  (More precisely, the 
distribution is 78% : 22%, the formula being 3/4 + (1/8) 
(1/4) to transportation.)  If the same proportions are 
imposed on local option taxes, the figures shown above 
should be reduced accordingly.


-90-

Sources

Calculations

The estimated state tax collection of $200 million from 
the NCTCOG Program  planning area was obtained as follows.  
From the State Comptrollers Office, 1985 tax collections were:

	Dallas County:    $109.1 million
	Tarrant County:   $ 61.1 million
	Two County Total: $170.2 million

Source: State of Texas Comptroller's Office, Annual 
        Report, Fiscal Year Ended 8/31/85, Texas 
        Comptroller of Public Accounts, Austin, Texas, 
        November 4, 1985.

The $170.2 million figure was divided by 0.895 to yield 
the NCTCOG "Old Intensive Study" area total and then 
multiplied by 1.05 to convert to the NCTCOG new planning 
area total of $199.7 million, rounded to $200 million. 
Scale factors are the VMT ratio of the NCTCOG.

Total motor fuel taxes collected for Texas in 1985 were 
$770.73 million. Employing NCTCOG scale factors of 0.111 
to yield the Dallas County estimated tax, and .062 to 
yield the Tarrant County Tax, those taxes were estimated 
as $85.6 million and $47.8 million, respectively, both 
equivalent to 78% of total tax collected, in turn 
equivalent to 3/4 + (1/8) (1/4) of the total.  

 Source: State of Texas Department of Highways sod 
         Public Transportation, Annual Financial Report for 
         Fiscal Year Ended August 31, 1985, unaudited, 
         Austin, Texas, 1985.

References

U. S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 
Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism 1985-86 
edition, Washington, D. C., 1986.

U. S. Federal Highway Administration, State Highway 
Cost-Allocation Guide, Vol. II Technical Appendix, 
Washington, D. C., October 1984.

Ronald McGuire, Florida Department of Transportation,
Office of Transportation Policy, MS 28, Burns Building,
Tallahassee, Florida 32301
904-487-4101


-91-

		    V. LOCAL SALES TAXES
			   Overview
Definition

A tax imposed on general merchandise, specific services 
and luxury items by most states and many local 
governments.  The tax is generally an ad valorem 
(percentage) tax and may have some portion dedicated to 
transportation.

Examples

Local sales taxes include rates of 3% in Baton Rouge, LA 
and 5% in New Orleans, LA (with a state sales tax of 4% 
in Louisiana).  Denver has a local sales tax of 3.67%, 
and Tulsa has one of 3%.  A number of cities have local 
sales tax rates of 1% to 2%.  Dallas has a 1% local sales 
tax plus a 1% sales tax for DART financing.

Financial Results

General sales taxes are the largest source of revenue for 
states, with receipts in 1983 ranging up to $7.8 billion 
for Texas.  Rates varied as of January 1, 1986 from 0% in 
five states to 7.5% in Connecticut.  Many cities have an 
additional sales tax which contributes to local revenues.  
In 1982, Chicago and Washington D.C. had receipts in 
excess of $400 million and Los Angeles received $369 
million while Dallas received about $115 million.  In 
1985, DART collected $155.2 million from the 
DART-dedicated sales tax, while collections on the 1% 
local tax in the NCTCOG policy area equalled $285 
million.

Of those states which apply the sales tax to motor fuel, 
only Georgia dedicates all motor fuel sales tax revenue, 
and Illinois and Mississippi dedicate part of these 
revenues to streets and highways.

Major Issues :

   Legal/Administrative Administrative problems can arise if 
   the sales tax rate varies among communities within a local 
   area.

   Political While taxes of any sort are unpopular, sales 
   taxes tend to be more acceptable than most other forms of 
   taxation.

   Economic Sales taxes tend to be regressive and the 
   services they finance do not generally benefit those who 
   pay the taxes.  They do provide a stable source of 
   revenue and respond quickly to changes in overall income 
   levels. It is important to account for the total level of 
   sales taxation as well as the local portion since it is 
   the total amount that will affect consumption 
   expenditures.


-92-

			V. LOCAL SALES TAX
				Detail

General Information

Table 10 presents detailed information on sales taxes for 
selected large cities and counties which have local as 
well as state sales taxes.  That table exhibits the Texas 
state sales tax at 4.125%, the rate as of 1986; in 1987, 
the state sales tax was raised to 5.25%, at least until 
Aug. 31, 1987. There were a number of local sales taxes 
in place, including Dallas  at 2% and Fort Worth at 
1.25%.  The Dallas tax includes a 1% Dallas Area Raid 
Transit (DART) sales tax which applies to DART member 
cities.  The Dallas and Fort Worth total state and local 
sales taxes are at roughly the same level as those in 
force for a number of large cities, including those in 
California, Colorado, Missouri, Ohio, Oklahoma and Utah.  
Cites with significantly higher levels include Chicago 
(8%), New Orleans (9%), New  51	York City (8.25%) and Seattle 
(7.9%).

NCTCOG Area Sales Tax Information

Data Resources, Incorporated has estimated DART sales tax 
collections as $155.2 million as of 1985.  In contrast, 
the sum of city sales tax collections was estimated as 
$171.5 million for member cities in the DART district.  
Although both amounts are derived from 1% sales taxes on 
the same base of taxable items, sales from within DART 
member cities to cities  not in the district are not 
subject to the DART tax, but are subject to city sales 
taxes.  The difference between $155.2 million and $171.5 
million is 12 percent, and though this seems a relatively 
high percentage and is based on limited experience to 
date, the DRI conclusion is that the percentage is likely 
to be stable over time (DRI, 1986, p. 32).


-93-

[GRAPHIC] /fnc15.gif>HERE for graphic.

-94-

[GRAPHIC] /fnc16.gif>HERE for graphic.

-95-

Table 11 exhibits 1985 sales tax collections for DART 
member cities, and demonstrates that there is great 
variation in per capita collections. Obviously, retail 
centers such as Addison and Farmers Branch can be 
expected to be well above primarily residential 
communities in per capita sales and sales tax; however, 
the difference is quite pronounced, with Addison having 
70 times as much sales tax per capita as Glenn Heights.  
It also seems worth remarking that Farmers Branch and 
Richardson have higher sales taxes per capita than does 
the City of Dallas.

The DRI projections of DART area sales taxes, in constant 
dollars, can be put in the form of indexes as follows:

	1985	100.0
	1990	120.0
	2000	161.9
	2010	213.6

Total sales in the Dallas-Fort Worth metropolitan areas 
amounted to $98.7 billion in 1985, with this breakdown 
between the two areas in million dollars:

Dallas Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA): $72,178.6
Fort Worth-Arlington MSA:                    26,479.1
                           		    $98,657.7

For the four counties corresponding to the NCTCOG Program 
Planning area, there was the following distribution of 
sales and of sales subject to tax (data from the State 
Comptrollers Office):


-96-

			  TABLE 11

		   SALES TAX COLLECTIONS
		  FOR DART MEMBER CITIES

		  1985 SALES TAX	    1985   SALES TAX
		IN THOUSAND DOLLARS	POPULATION   PER CAPITA

ADDISON		  4,032.1	    	  9,475		425.6
CARROLLTON	  5,832.9	   	 66,400	 	 87.8
COCKRELL HILL	     78.3	    	  3,075	 	 25.5
COPPELL		    284.4	    	  9,300	 	 30.6
DALLAS		112,475.3	  	938,425		119.9
FARMERS BRANCH	  5,532.0	   	 24,425		226.5
FLOWER MOUND	    202.4	   	 10,975		 18.4
GARLAND		  8,758.7	  	171,650	 	 51.0
GLENN HEIGHTS	     22.3	    	  3,675	  	  6.1
HIGHLAND PARK	    724.9	    	  8,975	 	 80.8
IRVING		 13,276.9	  	137,425	 	 96.6
PLANO	          9,038.2	  	105,600	 	 85.6
RICHARDSON	  9,374.6	   	 74,025		126.6
ROWLETT		    572.7	   	 13,700	 	 41.8
UNIVERSITY PARK	  1,287.7	   	 22,525	 	 57.2
OUTSIDE CITY OF	
DALLAS		 59,018.1	  	661,225	 	 89.3

NON-DALLAS, EXCLUDING

ADDISON	 	 54,986.0		651.750	         84.4
 
TOTAL		171,493.4		1,599,650	107.2

Data Sources: Population - NCTCOG, Current Population 
              1986 Estimates, May 1986.  1985 Populations = 
              Average of 1/1/85 and 1/1/86  population.

              Sales Tax -Data Resources Incorporated, Forecasts
              From the Dallas Area Rapid Transit Tax, May 1986.


-97-

	Sales Information in Million Dollars 1985

	Total Sales	      Sales Subject        Taxable Sales
				 to Tax             Divided By
                                                    Total Sales
				
Collin	2,534.993	         1,060.245		0.418
Dallas	65,223.451           	18,819.256		0.289
Denton	2,410.888	           955.206		0.396
Tarrant	25,386.182	         7,505.451		0.296

Total	93,385.715	        28,340.158		0.303

Thus, the NCTCOG area local sales tax collected, at 1 % 
of sales, approximately equaled $285 million as of 1985.

Potential For Increased Revenue, Local Sales Taxes
Share of DART 1%: Sales Tax As noted above, DART 
collected $155.2 million from its 1% local sales tax in 
1985.  A case can be made that a share of that tax ought 
to be allocated to highways because of the maintenance 
costs imposed on roads by DART buses, and more generally, 
to reflect DART bus use of the highway system.  No doubt, 
the imposition of such a distribution would meet with 
considerable resistance from the DART board and staff. 
Nonetheless, the proposal seems worth consideration.  If 
put into effect, these would be the financial result 
under alternative shares based on 1985 DART sales tax 
collections.  (One-twentieth share means one-twentieth of 
DART sales tax collections or .05 of the one percent DART 
sales tax, will be employed for, highways, and so on.)

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________
                                        
Share of DART Sales Tax	      155.2     ---    ---	 ---
	
- one-twentieth share	       ---      7.8    186	 281
- one-tenth share	       ---     15.5    372	 558
- one-fifth share	       ---     31.0    744	1116


-98-

General Sales Tax - NCTCOG Policy Planning Area As 
developed above, in 1985 the NCTCOG planning area had 
$28.5 billion in sales subject to sales tax. The current 
1% local sales tax consequently yielded $285 million 
annually. The effect of dedicating an additional 
fractional percentage of the sales tax to highway use 
would be as follows:

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________
                                        
General Sales Tax	      (285)    ---     --- 	---
- If add 0.25% dedicated to   ---     71.3     1710	 2565
  highways
- If add 0.50% dedicated to   ---    142.5     3420	 5130
  highways
- If add 1.00% dedicated to   ---    285.0     6840	10260
  highways

Expand Sales Subject to Sales Tax Sales subject to tax 
are only 30% of total sales in the NCTCOG area.  Sales 
subject to tax equaled $28.5 billion in 1985; total sales 
equaled $96.0 Billion; sales currently not subject to tax 
($96.0-$28.5 billion) equaled $67.5 billion.  If all of 
those sales were taxed and if an additional share were 
dedicated to highway use, the following revenue 
increments would be obtained:

______________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current      Increment
			       Level Annual  Projected   over
  Source of Revenue	       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total)   Level   Low -   High -
		                                Annual   Annual
		                                  x 24    x 36
______________________________________________________________									        Revenue in 

Making all Sales Subject to Tax, with:

0.l0% dedicated to highways     ---      67.5    1620	 2430
0.25% dedicated to highways	---     168.8    4050	 6075
0.50% dedicated to highways	---     337.5    8100	12150
1.00% dedicated to highways	---     675.0   16200	24300


-99-

Sources

Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 
Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1985-86 
edition, Washington, D. C., 1986.

Data Resource, Incorporated, Forecast of Revenues From 
the Dallas Area Rapid Transit Tax: State and Local 
Government Practice, Dallas (?), May 1986.

Contact: Frances Lawson, State Comptrollers Office, 
Austin, Texas, 512-463-4930.


-100-

			VI. PROPERTY TAXES
			     Overview

Definition

Taxes levied on both real and personal property.  While 
the taxes may be imposed at any level of government, they 
are usually collected and used by local jurisdictions.  
They are generally allocated out of the general fund and 
not dedicated in any part to transportation.

Examples

The effective tax rate is defined as the nominal rate 
times the assessment ratio; the assessment ratio is the 
ratio of assessed value to market value, and the nominal 
rate is the rate of taxation on assessed value.  In 1984, 
Newark, NJ had the highest effective rate of the largest 
cities in each state, at 6.29 per $100 of value; Casper, 
WY had the lowest effective rate at 0.59 per $100.  Most 
cities had rates between 1.00 and 2.50.  Houston's was 
1.68, ranking 24th out of the 50 cities covered.  In 
1978, the Dallas effective rate was about 20Z above 
Houston's; if that difference persisted in 1984, the 
Dallas effective rate was approximately $2 per $100 of 
value, equivalent to that of Chicago (1.99) and Omaha 
(1.98).  To view these results in broader perspective, 
note that: (1) Houston's total state and local tax rate 
was among the lowest of all large cities, and (2) Dallas 
and Houston are very close in that total rate (at least, 
as of 1978), differing by only a few percentage points 
(on the order of 3%).  Hence, there seems at least some 
potential for increases in state and local tax rates, 
including the property tax.

	Financial Results

In 1984, in Collin, Dallas, Denton and Tarrant counties, 
total county property taxes equalled $160.0 million and 
city property taxes equalled $526.1 million.  Hence, 
modest increases in tax rate can yield considerable 
increases in revenue; in particular, a one percent 
increase will yield $6.8 million.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative There are no problems with 
   collecting a property tax for general fund 
   purposes.  The legal situation for dedicating 
   property taxes to transportation uses is not clear.
 
   Political The property tax is one of the most 
   unpopular taxes. It is highly visible in that it is 
   paid in a lump sum, and it has been the focus of 
   voter resistance in the recent past.  Additionally, 
   underassessments and infrequent reassessments are 
   common.

   Economic The property tax is considered mildly 
   progressive.  Since it is a general tax, property 
   taxpayers do not necessarily receive equal public 
   services for equal contribution.  Any dedication of 
   part of the tax for transportation purposes would 
   likely increase this problem.
 

-101-

			VI . PROPERTY TAXES
				Detail

General Information

The Dallas-Fort Worth metropolitan area is very "typical" 
in its property tax collections, on a per capita basis.  
Table 12 exhibits the rankings of metropolitan areas in 
per capita property tax collected, as of 1982.  The 
Dallas-Fort Worth area with a per capita tax of $343 
ranked 87th of the 275 metropolitan areas; most of the 
areas had per capita collections ranging from $200 to 
$400 per person, which covers ranks 51 through 203, and 
accounts for more than half the total number of 
metropolitan areas.

Table 13 reinforces the image of Dallas-Fort Worth as 
typical, perhaps quintessentially so, for its per capita 
collection was essentially the same as the U.S. overall 
average of $341 per capita.  The U. S. metropolitan 
average was somewhat higher, at $366 per capita.  Table 
13 also shows per capita property tax collections for the 
components of the Dallas-Fort Worth metropolitan area.  
The entire area is defined as a CSMA, or consolidated 
metropolitan statistical area; the Dallas portion had a 
higher collection level, at $373 per capita, than did the 
Fort Worth portion, at $283 per capita.


Each of those components is termed a PMSA or primary 
metropolitan statistical area.  For each PMSA, the 
component counties are also listed, with collections per 
capita ranging from a low of $161 for Johnson County to a 
high of $410 for Dallas county.  Besides Dallas county, 
the major counties in the COG study area Collin, Denton 
and Tarrant - had fairly consistent collections per 
capita, ranging from $220 for Denton to values in the 
$290's for Collin and Tarrant.
		
Both Tables 12 and 13 exhibit a number of major 
metropolitan areas with property tax collections above 
that of the Dallas-Fort Worth area, with Houston a


-102-

TABLE 12

		PROPERTY TAXES COLLECTED PER CAPITA, 1982
			FOR SELECTED METROPOLITAN AREAS

			
                                Property Tax
Metropolitan Area	Per Capita 1982		Rank		
		
Atlantic City NJ               $739	  	  1
New York NY			636		  2
Detroit MI			585		  3	
Boston MA			567	  	  4
Hartford CT			554	  	  5
Saginaw MI			513	 	 10
Portland OR			480	 	 20
Houston TX			478	 	 21
Chicago IL			460	 	 27
Denver CO			399	 	 51
Philadelphia PA			363	 	 76
San Francisco CA		347	 	 84
Dallas-Fort Worth TX		343	 	 87
Los Angeles CA			302		112
Raleigh NC			274		138
Altoona PA			200		203
New Orleans LA			147		247
Baton Rouge LA			116		259
Las Cruces NN	 		 68		272
Tuacaloosa AL	 		 66		273
Anniston AL	 		 57		274
Montgomery AL	 		 52		275

Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, State and Metropolitan 
       Area Data Book, 1986,  Washington, D. C. 1986, Table 2, 
       XLII-XLV.  Coverage: 275 Metropolitan Areas.


-103-

			TABLE 13
	PROPERTY TAXES COLLECTED, TOTAL AND PER CAPITA, 1982,
		FOR SELECTED AREAS-DETAILED COMPARISONS

United States		$341		78,951.9

U.S. Metropolitan	366		64,433.9
U.S. Nonmetropolitan	262		14,518.0

Dallas-Fort Worth CMSA	343		 1,077.9
Dallas PMSA		373	  	   780.0
Fort Worth PMSA		283	  	   297.9

Dallas PMSA
  Collin Co		294	   	   48.3
  Dallas Co		410	  	  671.4
  Denton Co		220	   	   36.4
  Ellis Co		178	   	   11.3
  Kaufman Co		192	    	    8.1
  Rockwall Co		261	    	    4.3

Fort Worth PMSA
  Johnson Co		161	   	   11.8
  Parker Co		212	   	   10.2
  Tarrant Co		297	  	  275.9

Houston PMSA		471		1,446.4
New York NY PMSA	575		4,764.8
Washington D.C. MSA	468		1,559.6
Chicago IL PMSA		453		2,757.8
Denver CO CMSA		399	  	  687.3
Philadelphia PA CMSA	363		2,071.0

Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, State and Metropolitan 
        Area Data Book, 1986, Washington, D. C., 1986, pp. 16, 
        36, 56, 216, 276, 316.

MSA: Metropolitan Statistical Area, PMSA: Primary 
Metropolitan Statistical Area, CMSA: Consolidated 
Metropolitan Statistical Area.  See Dallas-Fort Worth as 
an example.


-104-

particularly notable case.  There is at least a hint here 
that there is same scope for increasing Dallas-Fort Worth 
rates without making them out of line
with the rates in other metropolitan areas.

Of course, the evidence presented above shows total 
collections, which consists of effective tax rates times 
the market value of property, and the effective rate can 
be viewed as a better indicator of tax level than amount 
collected. (Effective rate equals nominal rate times the 
assessment ratio; the assessment ratio is the ratio of 
assessed value to market value, and the nominal rate is the 
rate of taxation on assessed value.)  In 1984, for data 
covering the largest cities in each state, most cities 
had effective rates between 1.00 and 2.50, that is, taxes 
paid ranged from $1 to $2.50 per $100 of market value.  
Houston's was 1.68, ranking 24th of the 50 cities covered 
(U.S. Statistical Abstract, 1986, p. 293).  In 1978, the 
City of Dallas had property tax rates about 20% above 
those of Houston (Cummings, 1982, p. 37). If that 
relation held in 1984 as well, Dallas would have an 
effective rate around 2.00, roughly equal to that of 
Chicago and Omaha, and below a number of cities including 
St. Louis (2.15), Minneapolis (2.31), Portland, Maine 
(2.35) and Portland, Oregon (2.37).  Several cities had 
much higher rates, including Milwaukee (3.34) and Detroit 
(4.04).  

These data again suggest some scope for property 
tax increases, in the sense that an increase of 10 
percent or so would not move Dallas-Forth Worth "out of  
line" with experience elsewhere.  From Table 13, it can 
be seen that a 10% property tax increase would yield roughly 
$100 million annually, assuming that property values would not 
be affected by that increase.  his is a substantial amount, 
and could cover roughly half the "Mobility 2000" 
shortfall.  Of course, dedicating any or all of that 
increment to highway purposes would no doubt pose 
problems.)  n the next sections, the property tax is 
considered in some detail,


-105-

by viewing major components under the headings of county 
and city property taxes. (Since school district and 
hospital district property taxes are dedicated to schools 
and hospitals, respectively, they have not been 
considered.)

County Property Taxes

Collin, Dallas, Denton and Tarrant Counties account for 
the bulk of the NCTCOG planning area.  In 1984, those 
counties contained property with a combined appraised 
value of approximately 136 billion dollars, which was 20 
percent of the state total.  The distribution of 
appraised property values by type and county appears as 
Table 14.  According to the Texas State Property Tax 
Board, a county may levy as many as three individual 
property taxes for funds dedicated to specific purposes: 
The General Revenue Fund, Farm to Market Roads and Flood 
Control (F.M. & F.C.), and a special Road & Bridge Fund 
(Annual Report for Tax Year 1985, P. E-1).  Counties have 
various options about the way property in their 
jurisdiction is assessed, the rate at which it is taxed 
and the classes of property which are exempt from 
taxation.

Potential for Increased Revenue, County Property Taxes

Table 15 shows the magnitudes of various property tax 
exemptions, while Table 16 shows revenues raised by 
county property taxes in 1984.  Those tables will be 
employed in considering a variety of options for 
increasing property tax revenue, including increases from 
the General Property Tax, from the Road and Bridge Tax 
and from increased taxation of motor vehicles.


-106-

			     TABLE 14
	     APPRAISED VALUE BY TYPE OF PROPERTY FOR
	STATE OF TEXAS AND MAJOR NCTCOG AREA COUNTIES, 1984

Category	State	NCTCOG Area Counties
		 of		                       4 County
                Texas   Collin  Dallas Denton  Tarrant    Total
                _______________________________________________
                             In Million Dollars
                _______________________________________________

Residential	225,599  4,745   36,706  3,000  16,735   61,186
Land 
(unimproved)	111,660	 4,527   7,324   1,074    3,752  16,677
COMML, INDL 
and Other 	330,368  2,560   40,803  1,317   13,070  57,750
Vehicles	  2,051	   *          0      0      167	    167
Total        	669,578	11,832   84,833  5,391   33,724 135,780

                                   Percent of Total
                _______________________________________________
Residential	33.7	  40.1     43.3   55.7     49.6	   45.1
Land 
(unimproved)	16.7	  38.3      8.6   19.9     11.1	   12.3
COMM, INDL 
and Other	49.3	  21.6     48.1   24.4     38.8	   42.5
Vehicles	 0.3	   **       0.0    0.0      0.5	    0.1
Total	       100.0	 100.0    100.0  100.0    100.0	  100.0


* Less than .1 Million Dollars 
** Less than .01 per cent 
a Total of single family and multifamily residential
b Total of vacant lots and acreage
c Total of farm and ranch improvements; commercial and 
industrial real 
estate; oil, gas and minerals; banks, utilities, 
business personal and 
 intangible personal.

Source: State of Texas, Property Tax Board, Annual Report 
        for Tax Year 1984, Austin, Texas, Dec. 1985.


-107-

			TABLE 15
	VALUE OF VARIOUS PROPERTY TAX EXEMPTIONS
		FOR STATE OF TEXAS AND MAJOR
		 NCTCOG AREA COUNTIES, 1984

Source of	    State	NCTCOG Area Counties
Exemption            of	                       
                    Texas    Collin   Dallas   Denton  Tarrant    
                _______________________________________________
                             In Million Dollars
                _______________________________________________


General Revenue	  52,263     46    16,114     103	1,601
Homestead 
Exemptions	   NA        0   (14,680)       0	    0
Farm to Market & 
Flood Control	  32,831     0         0        0	1,959
Productivity	  56,800 2,380       631      469	  947

  Included in General Revenue Exemption
   NA: not available

Source: State of Texas, Property Tax Board, Annual Report 
        for Tax Year 1984,  Austin, Texas, Dec. 1985.

			        TABLE 16
	REVENUE RAISED THROUGH COUNTY PROPERTY TAXES, 1984

Type of Tax           State     NCTCOG Area 
Counties		of
	             Texas    Collin   Dallas   Denton  Tarrant
                     __________________________________________
	                       Tax Rates in Percent 
                     __________________________________________      

General Revenue	    0.21357  0.18160  0.13950  0.21160  0.11725
Farm to Market & 
Flood Control       0.02638      0.0      0.0      0.0  0.00804
Road and Bridge	    0.00769      0.0  0.00090      0.0      0.0

                                           
                       Tax Levy in Million Dollars
                    ___________________________________________
General Revenue     1,197.3	17.0     95.0      10.2	   36.4
Farm to Market & 
Flood Control        168.2	 0.0      0.0       0.0	    2.4
Road and Bridge       43.1	 0.0      0.6       0.0	    0.0

Total	           1,408.6	17.0     95.6      10.2	   38.8

  Computed as General Revenue Levy divided by (Total 
  appraised value- Productivity Reduction - General Revenue
  Exemption)
  Computed as F.M. & F.C. Levy/(Total appraised value - 
  F.M. & F.C. exempt)
  Computed as Road and Birdge Levy/Total appraised value 
  - Productivity  Reduction
  - General Revenue Exemption

Source: State of Texas, Property Tax Board, Annual Report 
        for Tax Year 1984, Austin, Texas, Dec. 1985.


-108-

Potential for Increased Revenue, County General Property 
Tax The tables on county property taxes (Tables 14, 15, 
and 16) yield the following information on appraised 
value, appraised value net of exemptions and total tax 
levy, in millions of dollars:

______________________________________________________________				                                       Appraised       
                                  Appraised     Total Tax Levy
                   Appraised      Value Net of      Revenue
                     Value         Exemptions      Collected
_______________________________________________________________
                             (million dollars)  
                   ____________________________________________
                   
State of Texas	    669,678        560,615            1197.3

NCTCOG Counties:
	
  Collin	     11,832	     9,406              17.0
  Dallas	     84,833         68,088              95.0
  Denton	      5,391	     4,819              10.2
  Tarrant	     33,724	    31,176              36.4

Total 4 Counties     135,780       113,489             158.6

Thus, the 1984 annual level of tax collections in the 
NCTCOG counties was $158.6 million.  Consequently, a tax 
increase of 5% would yield about $8 million, and one of 
10% would yield about $16 million per year, assuming that 
property values would be unaffected by the tax increase, 
and that current levels are close to those of 1984.

The current effective tax rate for the NCTCOG counties in 
percentage terms is  .13975%.  If this were raised to the 
state average rate of .21357%, revenue collected in the 
NCTCOG counties would equal $242.4 million, an increment 
of  revenue of approximately $85 million per year.  The 
effective state rate exclusive of the NCTCOG counties 
turns out to be .23231%.  If this effective rate were 
employed by the NCTCOG counties, the revenue collected 
would be $253.6 million, an increment of $105 million per 
year. (These figures are obtained as follows: .13975% 
comes from 158.6/113,489; .21357% from 1197.3/560,615; 
and  $242.4 million from .0021357 x 113,489. The 
effective rate exclusive of NCTCOG


-109-

counties equals (1197.3-158.6)/(560,615-113,489) = 
1038.7/447,126 = .0023231.  Finally, 263.6 is derived 
from .0023231 x 113,489.)

These calculations for current revenue and their 
implications for a 24 year time span are summarized as 
follows.
_____________________________________________________________
   		           Revenue in millions of dollars 
                	   Current    Increment
		           Level Annual Projected over
   Source of Revenue	   (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                            Total)   Level   Low-   High-
				           Annual  Annual
                                             x 24   x 36
_____________________________________________________________

County General Property Tax 158.6     ---      ---	---
-increase 5%                 ---       8      192	288
-increase 10%                ---      16      384	576
-Bring to state average rate ---      85     2040	3060
-Bring to rest of state 
 average rate                ---     105     2520	3780

Potential for Increased Revenue, County Road and Bridge 
Tax Of the four counties examined here, only Dallas 
County levies any tax at all for the Road and Bridge levy 
and even in that county the rate is far below the state 
average.  Additional revenues of approximately $8.1 
million dollar a year could be raised if Collin, Dallas, 
Denton and Tarrant county all levied a road and bridge 
tax at the state average rate of .00769.  This figure is 
obtained as follows.  Taxable property equals total 
appraised value (Table 14) minus property exempt from the 
road and bridge tax (the general property and 
productivity exemption from Table 15).  This base figure 
is $113,489 million (from 135,780-4,427-17,864, all in 
millions).  Multiplication by .00769 yields $8.7 million; 
subtracting the current Dallas County figure of $0.6 
million yields the increment of $8.1 million.  Hence, 
revenue calculations are as follows:


-110-

_____________________________________________________________
   		           Revenue in millions of dollars 
                	   Current    Increment
		           Level Annual Projected over
   Source of Revenue	   (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                            Total)   Level   Low-   High-
				           Annual  Annual
                                             x 24   x 36
_____________________________________________________________

Road & Bridge Property Tax   0.6      ---      ---	--
-Bring to state average rate ---      8.1      194      292

Potential for Increased Revenue, Appraise and Tax Motor 
Vehicles, County Tax Under Section 11.25 of the Texas 
Code, counties have the option of exempting personal 
motor vehicles from taxation.  Denton and Dallas County 
have, in fact, done so, although the city of Dallas does 
subject vehicles to its property tax.  Many other 
counties also exempt personal vehicles, and most of the 
counties that tax vehicles assess them at much less than 
their group market value.  This latter includes Collin 
County, which has an extremely limited tax, and Tarrant 
County, with a modest tax.  Current tax collections are 
inferred as follows:

           Number of  Appraised	   General     
           Vehicles   Value Per	   Tax Rate    Current revenue
	  Registered  Vehicle	    in %        in 000 dollars
Collin	  160,177	0.37	   0.1816           1.1
Dallas	1,590,940	  0        0.1395             0
Denton	  157,912	  0        0.2116             0
Tarrant	  923,596   $181.00	   0.1173         196.0

Inspection of a random sample of 15 Texas counties that 
do tax vehicles yielded per vehicle appraisals that 
ranged from a lower value of $13 to an upper value of 
$1,736, with an average value of $151.  These values were 
used to form a list of prospective appraisals, but since 
the $1,736 figure itself was viewed as relatively modest, 
a value of $3500 was added to the list as a "realistic" 
high appraised value.  Number of vehicles times appraised 
value times general  property tax rate yields the 
prospective current revenues shown as Table 17.


-111-

			TABLE 17
PROSPECTIVE REVENUE FROM APPLYING PROPERTY TAX TO MOTOR VEHICLES
					
                  Appraised	  Total Appraised     Revenue
                  Value Per	     Value in           in 000
County	          Vehicle	    000 dollars        dollars
	
Collin
 very low           $  13	  	 2,082         	  3.8
 low		      151	 	 24,187	  	 43.9
 medium		    1,736	 	278,067	  	505.0
 high		    3,500	        560,620	      1,018.1

Dallas
 very low	       13	         20,682	         28.9
 low		      151	        240,232	        335.1
 medium		    1,736	      2,761,872	      3,852.8
 high		    3,500	      5,568,290	      7,767.8

Denton
 very low	       13	          2,953	          6.3
 low		      151		 23,845	         50.5
 medium		    1,736		274,135	        580.1
 high		    3,500		552,692	      1,169.5

Tarrant
 very low	       13		 12,007	         14.1
 low		      151		139,436	        163.5
 medium		    1,736	      1,603,363	      1,879.9
 high		    3,500	      3,232,586	      3,790.2

Four-County Total

 very low	       13		137,724	         53.1
 low		      151		427,700	        593.0
 medium	            1,736	      4,917,437	      6,817.8
 high		    3,500	      9,914,188	     13,745.6


-112-

These results yield the following positive revenue 
increments.  (The $13 appraised case is omitted because 
it yields a revenue decrease.)

______________________________________________________________	
			   Revenue in millions of dollars
			   Current       Increment
			   Level Annual Projected over
   Source of Revenue	   (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                           Total) Level   Low-  High-
                                        Annual  Annual
                                          x 24   x 36

Appraise and Tax Motor 
  Vehicles                  0.2    ---    ---    ---
-"Low" - appraised value 
  per vehicle-$151	    ---    0.4    9.6   14.4
-"Medium" appraised value 
  per vehicle=$1736	    ---    6.6  158.4  237.0
-"High" - appraised value 
  per vehicle=3500	    ---   13.5  324.0  486.0

City Property Taxes

City property taxes were analyzed by developing data on 
the 59 cities in Collin, Dallas, Denton and Tarrant 
Counties that had populations of 2,500 and over in 1984.  
For those cities, Table 18 exhibits 1984 taxable property 
values, tax rates, tax levies and homestead exemptions as 
percentages of property values.

Potential for Increased Revenue, City Property Taxes

Applying the data in Table 18, four tax increase 
approaches were considered:

1. Increase the property tax rate by 5 percent.

2. Increase the tax rate in each city by 5 cents per $100 
   assessed value, that is, add .05 to the tax rates shown in 
   Table 18.

3. Eliminate the homestead exemption in those cities 
   currently employing it.

4. Raise the tax rate by 11 percent and simultaneously 
   increase the homestead exemption by 10 percent (where 
   legally permissible) to keep most homeowners' tax 
   payments virtually unchanged while increasing 
   revenue.


-113-

			TABLE l8

1984 CITY TAX DATA: TAXABLE VALUE, TAX RATE, TAX LEVY AND 
HOMESTEAD
 EXEMPTIONS FOR CITIES WITH 2500 OR MORE POPULATION  LOCATED
       IN FOUR MAJOR COUNTIES OF NCTCOG PLANNING AREA

	                                                               
						     Homestead
			              1984 Tax Levy  Exemptions
	  Taxable Value   Tax Rate    in Thousand  As Percent of
County     in Million  ( in Percent)     Dollars      Property 
and city    Dollars                                   Values

Collin Co.

1. Allen              431.26	.42500     1,832.85	 0
2. Frisco	      199.93	.24000       479.84	 0
3. McRinney	      554.06	.69000     3,823.01	 0
4. Plano	    4,901.64	.45000    22,057.37	20
5. Princeton	       36.53	.42000       153.41	 0
6. Wylie	       97.10	.49000       475.77	 0
   Total	    6,220.52	          28,822.25

Dallas Co.

1 . Addison          1,885.13   .32000     6,032.42	40
 2. Balch Springs      229.38   .49530     1,136.13	 0
 3. Carrollton       3,405.85   .44000    14,985.73	10
 4. Cedar Hill         294.39	.50980     1,500.78	 0
 5. Cockrell Hill       40.60	.43000       174.59	 0
 6. Coppell            374.32   .46000     1,721.90	 0
 7. Dallas          42,126.11	.49180   207,176.19	40
 8. DeSoto             571.45   .52350     2,991.55	 0
 9. Ducanville         920.51   .56000     5,154.87	 0
10. Farmers Branch   2,569.37   .40000    10,277.50	40
11. Garland          5,009.68   .39550    19,813.29	 0
12. Grand Prairie    2,746.75   .38830    10,665.65	 0
13. Highland Park      894.02   .27000     2,413.84	40
14. Hutchins            78.33	.46000       360.32	 0
15. Irving           6,126.34	.36290    22,232.49	22
16. Lancaster          399.37	.62000     2,476.09	 0
17. Mesquite         2,239.08	.48000    10,747.57	 0
18. Richartaon       4,113.72   .32050    13,184.48	 0
19. Rowlett            343.95	.41390     1,423.62	10
20. Seagoville         113.30	.42000       475.85	 0
21. University Park 1, 149.09	.39000     4,481.45	40
     Total          75,630.74	         339,426.31

Denton Co.

1. Colony	       343.81	.38000       1,306.47	 0
2. Denton	     1,154.04	.59000       6,808.81	10
3. Flower Mound	       247.50	.37340         924.18	 0
4. Highland Village    116.46	.46400         540.38	 0
5. Lake Dallas	        60.88	.36700         223.43	 0
6. Lewisville	       943.56	.51000       4,812.17	 0
7. Sanger             	44.98	.48500         218.16	 0
   Total	     2,911.23	            14,833.60



-114-

			TABLE 18 ( continued)

	                                                               
						     Homestead
			              1984 Tax Levy  Exemptions
	  Taxable Value   Tax Rate    in Thousand  As Percent of
County     in Million  ( in Percent)     Dollars      Property 
and city    Dollars                                   Values

Tarrant Co.

 1. Arlington	     6,379.55	.45200      28,835.57	30
 2. Azle	       168.85   .30000	       506.54	 0
 3. Bedford	     1,118.98	.36000	     4,028.33	 0
 4. Benbrook	       499.25	.46000	     2,296.54	 0
 5. Colleyville	       329.03	.52000	     1,710.96	 0
 6. Crowley	       117.09	.40160	       470.22	 0
 7. Edgecliff Village	76.04	.18477	       140.50	 0
 8. Euless	       765.36	.44000	     3,367.57	30
 9. Everman	        80.49	.49000	       394.38	 0
10. Forest Hill	       209.62	.57000	     1,194.85	 0
11. Fort Worth      11,606.54	.67650	    78,518.21	15
12. Grapevine	     1,042.55	.40000	     4,170.20	 0
13. Haltom City	       620.17	.41000	     2,542.70	 0
14. Hurst	       948.18	.43500	     4,124.57	20
15. Keller	       224.96	.31000	       697.38	 0
16. Kennedale	        79.50	.41850	       332.70	 0
17. Lake Worth	       110.00	.22875	       251.63	 0
18. Mansfield	       306.45	.53810	     1,648.99	 0
19. N.Richland Hills 1,034.45	.34500	     3,568.85	10
20. Richland Hills     223.49	.30640	       684.76	 0
21. River Oaks	       105.99	.42810	       453.73	 0
22. Saginaw	       239.73	.44000	     1,054.83	 0
23. Southlake	       214.81	.18100	       388.81	 0
24. Watauga	       294.65	.29984	       883.48	 0 
25. White Settlement   265.67	.30000         797.02	 0
     Total          27,061.40	           143,063.29


a tax rate in fraction form is listed value times .01.  
For example, the Arlington rate tax in fraction form is 
.0045200.  Then, Arlington's taxable value in thousands 
of dollars is 6,379,550.  That value times .00452 equals 
28,835.57, the tax levy in thousands of dollars.
 
Source of data: State of Texas, State Property Tax Board, 
                Annual Report for Tax Year 1984, Austin 
                Texas, December, 1985.


-115-

Approach 1 is obviously straightforward, involving simple 
multiplication.  In considering Approach 2, which 
consists of adding 5 cents per $100 of assessed value to 
the tax rate, note that in the case of Allen in Collin 
County, this implies changing the percentage tax rate 
shown in Table 18 from .425 to .475, or changing the rate 
per dollar to $.00475, or the rate per hundred dollars to 
47.5 cents.  Approaches 3 and 4 involve the homestead 
exemption.  In 1984, cities in Texas had a local option 
to exempt up to 40 percent of the value of homesteads 
from property taxation.  (In 1985 to 1987 the maximum 
legal limit on homestead exemptions drops to 30 percent 
and after 1987 it will be 20 percent.)  Although many 
cities choose not to take this option, 15 area cities, 
including both Dallas and Fort Worth, did choose to 
exempt at least some part of homesteads' valuation from 
property taxation.  One way in which additional property 
tax revenue could be raised without an increase in the 
tax rate would be to eliminate these exemptions, yielding 
Approach 3.  Approach 4 assumes the simultaneous increase 
of the tax rate by 11 percent and the homestead exemption 
by 10 percent, which would imply that most homeowner's 
tax liability would be virtually unchanged, while 
additional revenue would be raised from land uses other 
than homesteads.  Current revenues and revenues collected 
under each approach considered are as follows (in 
millions of dollars):
Revenue Collections in Millions of Dollars

	  Current    Approach 1	Approach 2  Approach 3   Approach 4

Collin	  28.8	 	 30.3	   31.9		 30.6	 30.7
Dallas	 339.4		356.4	  377.2		380.7	347.0
Denton	  14.8		 15.6	   16.3		 15.2	 15.6
Tarrant	 143.1		150.2	  156.6		153.8	151.4
Total	 526.1		552.5	  582.0		580.3	544.7

Applying these totals yields the following revenue 
increments.


-116-
	
_______________________________________________________________
	                      Revenue in millions of dollars
		              Current      Increment
		              Level Annual Projected over
	Source of Revenue     (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                    Annual   Annual
	                                      x 24   x 36
_______________________________________________________________

City Property Tax Collections   526.1	---	---	---
-Increase 5%		         ---	26.4	 633	 950
-Increase tax rate in each 
  city by .05                    ---	55.9	1340	2010
-Eliminate homestead exemption	 ---	54.2	1300	1950
-Raise local tax rate 11% and 
 increase homestead exemption 
 10% - shifts tax burden toward
  non-residential property       ---	18.6	 446	 670

Sources
	
State of Texas, Property Tax Board, Annual Report for Tax 
Year 1984, Austin, Texas, December, 1985.

State of Texas, Property Tax Code, Chapter 11, Section 
11.25.

State of Texas, Department of Highways and Public 
Transportation, Transportation Planning Division and 
Finance Division, Texas Transportation Finance Facts, 
1984.

The sources of the appraised values for vehicles were:

	"Very low" - The lowest appraised value by counties 
                     appraising  vehicles, that of Shelby Co. 
                     ($13)

	"Low" -      The current average of appraised value 
                     by all counties  carrying out appraisals. 
                     ($151)

	"Medium" -   The current maximum appraised value, 
                     by Donley Co. ($1736)

	"High" -     Approximately twice the medium ($3500)

The City of Dallas does appraise and tax motor vehicles 
as a component of the city property tax.  The values 
shown are for county property taxes.


-117-

	VII. VEHICLE LICENSE FEES AND REGISTRATION FEES
			Overview

Definition

A variety of fees and taxes imposed by most states on 
vehicle owners as part of the vehicle registration 
process.  These are usually considered a charge for 
access to the system and are not based on the use of the 
system.  Some part may  be returned to the locality.

Examples

Florida, Pennsylvania, Texas

Financial Results

Revenues are generally significant and predictable over 
time. In Florida in fiscal year 1986 about $294 million 
was generated from license fees and registrations, 
excluding mobile homes.  Of this amount, $227 million 
went to the state Department of Transportation.  In 
Pennsylvania, $410 million was collected from licenses 
and registration during 1985/86 with a basic drivers 
license costing $5/yr and registration $24/yr.  In 1984 
the state of Texas collected $382 million in registration 
fees.  In the NCTCOG Program planning area, $90.4 million 
was collected in general registration fees. In addition, 
currently about $15 million is collected by a $5 charge 
per vehicle for county road and bridge fees.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative There are no problems with most 
  vehicle fees as they have been a traditional mechanism 
  for raising revenues and regulating vehicles for many 
  years.  There is a high administrative cost, usually 
  viewed as necessary given the regulatory importance of 
  licensing and registration.

  Political The taxes are often considered progressive in 
  that they tax upper-income individuals who tend to own 
  cars.  However since they are collected at a single point 
  in time they are more visible than taxes collected over 
  time and are therefore more likely to be scrutinized by 
  the public.

  Economic The fees are often justified on regulatory 
  grounds as opposed to revenue grounds.  Since the high 
  administrative costs associated with these fees would 
  exist in any event because of their regulatory 
  importance, their use for revenue generation involves 
  minimal additional cost.


-118-

		VII. VEHICLE REGISTRATION FEES
			Detail
Texas vehicle registration fees currently consist of 
general registration "license fees" and the County Road and 
Bridge Fee of $5 per vehicle.  Each will be considered in turn.

General Registration "License Fees"

Current Operation When Texas counties collect revenue for 
motor vehicle registration, a portion of it is retained 
for county use in the locally controlled County Road and 
Bridge Fund and a portion is passed on to the State 
Highway Fund.  Under the current legislative formula, 
approved in Senate Bill 150 in 1981, counties "...retain 
the first $50,000 plus $350 for each mile of county 
maintained roads up to 500 miles.  Thereafter the county 
retains fifty percent of the next $250,000.  Under this 
formula a county may retain up to $350,000...  The 
remainder of the money collected goes to the State 
Highway Fund." (p. 34)

Thus some counties pass the vast majority of registration 
fees to the state while others retain a significant 
share.  In 1984, for example, Tarrant County passed 
$26,955,942 in registration fees to the state fund and 
kept only $350,000 in revenues.  Rusk County also kept 
$350,000 in revenues but passed only $847,842 to the 
state.  Because the counties in the NCTCOG area have very 
high levels of vehicle registration, the portion of motor 
vehicle registration fees retained for local use tends to 
be very small.  In total, Collin, Dallas, Denton and 
Tarrant County paid more than ninety million dollars to 
the state for vehicle registration fees in 1984 but 
retained only the amounts allowed by formula - The 
$350,000 cap in the case of Collin, Denton and Tarrant 
County, and $338,000 in the case of Dallas County 
(because it maintained somewhat less than


-119-

500 miles of road.)  Consequently, while the State of 
Texas returned an average of 21.7 percent of registration 
revenues to counties, the four NCTCOG counties received 
only about 1.5 percent of locally generated registration 
revenue.

Potential for Increased Revenue, General Registration 
"License Fees"

Counties in the local area could raise substantially 
increased revenues if the $350,000 cap were lifted or if 
the funds were distributed on the basis of a formula that 
weighted local inputs to the state coffers more heavily. 
The following tabular enumeration shows local revenue 
retained locally under the current system and under three 
alternative formulas.

	1984 Allocation of Vehicle Registration Fees
	                  County Receipts (000's of $)
                         _______________________________
				                                
                                             Propor-   propor-
                                             tional    tional
                     Total                     To        To
         Total   Collections          No-Cap: Dollars: Vehicles:
County Vehicles (000's of $)  Current  For-    For-      For-
                                      mula(1) mula(2)  mula (3)

Collin	  160,177   4,574      350    2,512     993     1,124
Dallas 1,590,940   51,855      338   26,141  11,257    11,162
Denton	 157,912    4,594      350    2,522     997     1,108
Tarrant	 923,596   29,120      350   14,785   6,321     6,478
	
4 County
Total  2,832,625   90,413    1,388   45,960  19,568    19,872
	
State 13,508,355  436,586   94,774    N.A.   94,774    94,774

The entries under the heading of Formula (1) show the 
amount of revenue local governments would be allowed to 
retain if the state simply lifted the $250,000 cap on the 
amount of registration fees of which the county retained 
50 percent.  This sort of plan would, of course, cost the 
state highway fund a great deal of revenue.  Under this 
plan, Collin, Dallas, Denton, and Tarrant counties would 
have received almost forty-six million dollars in 1984. 
This is more than thirty-three times as much as they 
actually received.


-120-

An alternative approach would be to allow the state to 
retain its current (78 percent) share of vehicle 
registration revenues but to distribute the remaining 
revenues to counties on the basis of total revenues paid 
in by each county.  Entries under the heading of Formula 
(2) show the distribution of revenues in this case.  As a 
final alternative, the state again would retain its 
current share of vehicle registration revenue but local 
revenues would be allocated on the basis of number of 
vehicles registered rather than dollars collected, with 
the distribution of revenues shown under the heading of 
Formula (3).  Of course, Formulas (2) and (3) are quite 
similar, and yield approximately the same total local 
revenue - about 14 times the current amount collected. 
Summarizing these results and their implications for 
future levels of revenue, the following is obtained.

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current       Increment
			       Level Annual Projected over
       Source of Revenue       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                     Annual Annual
			                       x 24  x 36
______________________________________________________________

General Registration Fees

90.4 million collected by state  (90.4)    ---    ---	---
1.4 million returned to counties   1.4     ---    ---	---
Given minimum amount at l00% 
retention byformula, and then:

- county retains 50% of receipts  ---     44.6    1070	1605
- total to counties in proportion 
  to revenue paid	          ---     18.2     437	 655
- total to counties in proportion 
  to vehicles registered          ---     18.5     444	  666
		

County Road and Bridge Fees

Current Operation Currently, counties have the option of 
collecting a fee of $5 per passenger vehicle as a road 
and bridge fee, in addition to the general state 
registration fee.  The tax was put into effect by the 
state legislature and may 


-121-

be changed only by state legislation.  Of the $5 fee, 
$4.85 is retained by the county and 0.15 is turned over 
to the state.

Potential for Increased Revenue, County Road and Bridge 
Fees There are approximately 3 million vehicles in the 
NCTCOG Program Planning area, yielding current revenues 
of $15 million, given a $5 fee per vehicle, with $4.85 
retained locally.  The effect of increased fees are then 
easily calculated, with 3 million x $4.85 yielding $14.55 
million.

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current       Increment
			       Level Annual Projected over
       Source of Revenue       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                     Annual Annual
			                       x 24  x 36
______________________________________________________________                                           Revenue in 

	
County Road and Bridge Fees	14.55     ---   ---	---
- Raise fee $1 to $6	         ---      2.9    70	105
- Raise fee to $10	         ---     14.6   350	525

Sources

State of Texas Department of Highways and Public 
Transportation, Transportation Planning Division and 
Finance Division, Texas Transportation Finance Facts, 
Austin, Texas, 1984.

Unpublished calculations of State of Texas Department of 
Highways and Public
Transportation, Motor Vehicle Division, Allocation of 
Vehicle Registration Fees.  Austin, Texas (Available in 
UTD library under call number H 1409.6 R263 fee).

State of Texas, General & Special Laws, Vol 1, 67th 
Legislature Regular Session, 1981, chapter 1-506, pp 
473-476.

Contact: David Garrett, Accounting Division, Dallas 
County


-122-

	VIII. NEW TYPES OF TAXES AND REVENUE SOURCES
 			VIII. A PAYROLL TAX
			     Overview
Definition

A percentage tax on all payrolls in a defined geographic 
area, considered a business expense for corporate tax 
purposes.  Exemptions may be given to specified 
non-profit organizations.  Tax coverage may include those 
who are self-employed.

Examples

Portland, OR; Cincinnati, OH.

Financial Results

Significant revenues may be generated at low cost which 
may be completely or partially dedicated to 
transportation purposes.  A three county area including 
Portland, Oregon collected $47 million net of collection 
costs in fiscal year 1986 with a 0.6 percent payroll tax.  
The revenues were dedicated to transit purposes.  
Cincinnati, Ohio has an 0.3 percent tax, applying both to 
city residents and workers, with revenue going into a 
fund for transit operations.   In 1986, the fund had a 
balance of $18 million.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative A payroll tax requires 
  state-enabling legislation and may be restricted or 
  prohibited by state constitutions.  After being 
  challenged in court by the Portland business community it 
  was found to be a constitutional tax.

  Political The tax may be unpopular to the business 
  community.  If the tax is collected at the employer 
  level, however, the tax may be relatively invisible to 
  the average working person.

  Economic It can partly be justified by the gains to 
  employers from a more reliable work force due to better 
  traffic conditions and from an increase in labor morale 
  due to reductions in traffic congestion.  There are 
  questions concerning its equity due to the varying 
  degrees that workers and employers rely on the 
  transportation network.


-123-

	VIII. NEW TYPES OF TAXES AND REVENUE SOURCES

		  VIII.B AVIATION FUEL TAX

			 Overview
Definition

A tax placed on commercial and/or noncommercial aviation 
fuel.  The revenue may be used for non-aviation purposes 
such as highway construction.

Example

Florida

Financial Results

Florida has a 5.70 per gallon tax on aviation fuel 
purchased in the state. The current net yield after 
deductions for charges and a rebate to airlines based on 
wages paid by them to in-state employees is approximately 
$30 million a year.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative The use of an aviation fuel 
   tax has been challenged by both domestic and 
   foreign carriers in court.  The argument has been 
   that it is unconstitutional to charge an aviation 
   fuel tax that is used for highway construction.  
   The Florida Supreme Court found it legal in 1983 
   and, on appeal to the U.S. Supreme Court, it was 
   also found constitutional for both domestic and 
   foreign carriers.

   Most states have some form of aviation fuel tax.  
   The two forms primarily in use are (1) prorating 
   the tax to apply to fuel actually used while 
   operating within the state and (2) taxing all fuel 
   purchases in the state regardless of the locations 
   traveled.

   Political Public acceptance has been relatively 
   high since the tax is not very visible.  Airlines 
   have strenuously opposed it and have sought to 
   reduce their purchases of in-state fuel by using 
   exempted bonded fuel and by tankering of fuel.

   Economic Airports generate concentrated highway use 
   both in the short and long term, and additional 
   development in the long term, adding to 
   transportation requirements.  Hence, the tax can be 
   viewed as a form of impact fee.


-124-

			VIII. C LOTTERY

			    Overview

Definition

A game of chance in which prizes are distributed on the 
basis of winning numbers drawn by lot.  Lotteries are 
conducted by 22 states and the District of Columbia and 
involve a number of functions including marketing, 
printing and distributing tickets, maintaining sales 
outlets and developing rules and regulations for 
conducting each game.  Only two states dedicate a portion 
of lottery receipts to transportation.

Examples

Arizona, Pennsylvania (Dedicate some receipts to 
transportation)

Financial Results

Gross revenues from lotteries vary from $5.2 million in 
Vermont to almost $1.3 billion in Pennsylvania with net 
revenues to the state ranging from $1.2 million in 
Vermont to $600 million in New York.  The revenues will 
vary by the number and type of games offered and the 
number of players.  Revenue of $23 million was generated 
for transportation in 1985/86 in Arizona.  In 
Pennsylvania the $586 million raised in revenue in 
1985/86 was dedicated to Senior Citizens programs with 
transit programs aiding Senior Citizens explicitly 
specified.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative There must be state-enabling 
  legislation for the state or locality to operate a 
  lottery.  This may (as in Texas) require a 
  constitutional amendment.

  Political There is strong opposition from religious 
  groups who equate lotteries with the sins of 
  gambling, by those who feel it will attract 
  organized crime and by those who feel the poor will 
  be hurt by it. Nevertheless the public in most 
  states appear to support lotteries as every state 
  that has had a public referendum on a lottery has 
  given it a majority vote.

  Economic A lottery is a voluntary program and since 
  participation is on a voluntary basis, the program 
  can be viewed as efficient.  It is often argued 
  that lotteries are inequitable because the poor and 
  those with little education play the most.  
  However, one study found that the largest group of 
  players were those in the $25,000 to $40,000 a year 
  group and that most players had completed high 
  school and a significant number (40 percent) had 
  finished college.  Concerns are also expressed 
  about encouragement of compulsive gambling, but it 
  seems plausible that compulsive gamblers will seek 
  out other forms of gambling in any event - legal or 
  illegal.


-125-

			VIII.A PAYROLL TAX
				
				Detail

Case Example - Ohio 

Cincinnati has a tax officially designated as a payroll 
earnings tax that falls under the heading of a payroll tax.  
The tax of 0.3 percent is deducted from the paycheck of 
employees who either live or work in the City of Cincinnati. 
Revenue raised goes into the Transit Fund where it is used to 
pay for operating expenses.

The tax was locally passed in 1972 and put into effect in 
1973, empowered by the state which at the time did not 
have a state income tax.  Politically there was little 
problem in passing the original tax, in large part due to 
the city's intention of purchasing and operating a nearly 
bankrupt private transit system and lowering the bus fare 
to 25 cents.  Recent attempts to broaden the tax to 
include surrounding counties, however, have failed.

In 1986, the fund had a balance of $18 million.  This 
represents a significant portion of the $42 million 
budget for transportation administered in part by the 
Southwest Ohio Regional Transit Authority.  There have 
been moves recently to either allow the fund to be used 
for repairing streets or to actually give control of the 
revenue raised to the city for allocation. Both moves 
have, to date, been resisted.

In fiscal year 1986, the payroll tax netted $44 million 
after collection costs.  The self-employment tax netted 
$2. 7 million.  The collection costs are fairly low, 
averaging about two percent of revenues. Compliance with 
the tax is considered high.


-126-

The business community has lobbied against use of the tax 
but in a court challenge it was found to be 
constitutional.  It is considered to be a fairly  
invisible tax to the average working person since it is 
collected at the firm rather than at the employee level.

Case Example - Oregon
Oregon is the only state to date that has allowed a 
payroll tax to be used to generate revenues for transit 
financing.  The Tri-County Metropolitan Transportation 
Authority, composed of 15 cities centered around 
Portland, has imposed a 0.6 percent gross payroll tax, 
the maximum permitted by the 1970 state legislation.  The 
revenue may be used for both operating and capital 
expenditures, but operating costs must be paid first from 
the payroll tax.

The tax is collected quarterly from businesses by the 
State Department of Revenue.  There is no limit to the 
amount that can be collected from businesses.  The 
self-employed were not originally subject to the tax, but 
they have since  been included through a 0.6 percent 
self-employment tax based on net income.  State 
government agencies operating in the area are also 
included, with the state contributing an amount 
equivalent to what would be collected by the tax.  There 
are exemptions to the tax including Health Maintenance 
Organizations, farm laborers and non-profit 
organizations.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Payroll Tax
The Portland, Oregon gross payroll tax of 0.6 % and the 
Cincinnati, Ohio gross
payroll tax of 0.3% are both employed in transportation 
finance and can be viewed as benchmark levels.  Estimated 
Dallas-Fort Worth metropolitan area income equalled $51.9 
Billion in 1985 (DRI data).  For the United States, 
payroll as a share of income equals approximately 60 
percent.  (From Survey of Current Business, June 1986, 
p.7: U.S. wage and salary income relative to total


-127-

personal income was .595.)  Hence, the Dallas-Fort Worth 
metro area payroll can be estimated as currently about 
$30 billion.  Payroll tax proceeds then are as follows:

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current       Increment
			       Level Annual Projected over
       Source of Revenue       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                     Annual Annual
			                       x 24  x 36
______________________________________________________________                                           Revenue in 

 Payroll Tax 	             0     ---      ---     ---
- 0.1% payroll tax	    ---    30       720    1080
- 0.3% payroll tax	    ---    90      2160    3240
- 0.6% payroll tax	    ---   180      4320    6480

Sources

Contact (Oregon): David Auxier
                  Tri-County Metropolitan Transportation
                      District
                  4012 S.E. 17th Avenue
                  Portland, OR 97202

                   503- 39-6401
Contact (Ohio): Thomas Ford, Internal Auditor
                Southwest Ohio Regional Transit Authority
	        432 Walnut, Suite 1108
                Cincinnati, OH 45202

                513-651-3020

References:

Rice Center, A Guide to Innovative Financing Mechanisms 
for Mass Transportation - An Update.  Final Report 
(Preliminary), Prepared for Urban Mass Transportation 
Administration, December, 1985.

Data Resources Incorporated (DRI), Forecast of Revenues 
from the Dallas Area Rapid Transit Tax: State and Local 
Government Practice, May, 1986.


-128-
		VIII.B AVIATION FUEL TAX
			
			Detail

General Information

It can be argued that airports generate sad concentrate 
traffic, both by way of trips to and from airports, and - 
in the long run - by generating real estate development 
near airports.  Hence, it can further be argued that 
impact fees ought to be imposed on airports, with one 
version taking the form of taxes on fuel use by 
airplanes. Magnitudes of aviation fuel have been 
estimated as 1540 million gallons of aviation fuel for 
the state of Texas as a whole in 1985, with 2200 million 
gallons of use forecast for the year 2000.

Two-thirds of U.S. airline passengers enplane at large 
hubs, with Dallas-Fort Worth and Houston comprising the 
large hubs in Texas.  Of those two, the Dallas-Fort Worth 
(D/FW) airport handles twice the passenger load of 
Houston (18.5 million versus 9.2 million).  Assuming that 
Dallas-Fort Worth and Houston handle two-thirds of the 
state's air traffic between them implies that D/FW 
handles approximately 45 percent of the traffic, and 
presumably uses 45 percent of the fuel (based on data in 
1986 Statistical Abstract, p. 618).  In turn, given 1540 
million gallons of fuel for the state implies about 700 
million gallons of use annually in the local area.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Aviation Fuel Tax
Assuming 700 million gallons of aviation fuel use locally 
yields the following tax estimates for the listed tax 
rates:


-129-

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current       Increment
			       Level Annual Projected over
       Source of Revenue       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                     Annual Annual
			                       x 24  x 36
______________________________________________________________                                           Revenue in 

Aviation Fuel Tax

- If 1˘ tax/gal.	       ---       7      168    252
- If 2˘ tax/gal.	       ---      14      336    504
- If 10˘ tax/gal.	       ---      70     1680    2520

Sources

Texas Aeronautical Facilities Plan, August , 1984; 
Citations from that source were obtained from Merle 
Goodwin, Department of Transportation, Texas Aeronautics 
Commission.

Contact:  Ronald McGuire
	  Florida Department of Transportation
	  Office of Transportation Policy, MS28
	  Burns Building, Tallahassee, FL 32301
	  904-487-4101


-130-

			VIII.C LOTTERY

			    Detail
General Information

In 1985, the nation's 23 state lotteries grossed $9.99 
billion with a net return to state governments of $4.05 
billion.  The new California lottery sold more than $800 
million in tickets in its first three months and netted 
$270 million.  First year sales seem likely to exceed $2 
billion.  In 1985, the eight most populous lottery states 
sold an average of $94 in lottery tickets per state 
resident and netted $38 per resident.  Similar financial 
results in Texas would mean $1.5 billion in gross revenue 
and about $600 million a year in net receipts.  No state 
has ever lost money on a lottery, and no lottery measure 
has ever been defeated in a public vote.  Polls in 
lottery states reflect strong public support, and a poll 
in Texas in 1984 revealed 66 percent support for a 
lottery in the state.

Case Example - Arizona

Arizona currently runs a parimutuel weekly game called 
"The Pick" and has run an instant prize game since the 
passage of a citizen's initiative in November 1980.  The 
prize amounts are determined by weekly sales and the 
number of winners for that week. The lottery is scheduled 
for reconsideration in 1991.

Revenues after prizes and costs are earmarked for 
transportation projects in cities and towns and may be 
used either for operating or capital expenditures.  In 
addition, if the maximum allowed by law is deposited into 
the transportation fund, then cities are allowed to use 
up to 10 percent of the funds as matching revenue for 
cultural projects.  An exception to this is that cities 
with a population over 300,000, consisting of Phoenix and 
Tucson, must use the funds for operating or capital 
expenditures devoted to mass transit.


-131-

For the year ended June 30, 1986, the Arizona lottery 
grossed $121 million. Of this amount, 45 percent was 
legally required to be allocated to prizes and 6 percent 
to retailer commissions.  Local transportation is 
entitled to 30 percent of gross revenues to a maximum of 
$23 million with any excess alloted to the Highway User 
Revenue Fund.  For fiscal year 1986 this resulted in 
cities and towns getting the maximum $23 million, 
allocated to them on the basis of population.  An 
additional $14 million was deposited to the Highway User 
Revenue Fund.

Phoenix, the largest city in Arizona, received $8.4 
million in fiscal year 1986 which it used for a variety 
of mass transit programs.  Tucson, the second largest 
city, received almost $3.6 million, representing 
approximately 23 percent of the city's mass transit 
operating and maintenance budget.  Mesa, a city not 
required to use its lottery revenues solely for mass 
transit, allocated a large portion of its approximately 
$1.9 million to purchasing rights-of-way and street 
construction.

Case Example - Pennsylvania

Pennsylvania has had a lottery since 1972 which dedicates 
proceeds to the State Department of Aging and the 
Department of Transportation.  The revenues are required 
to benefit senior citizens.
	
In Fiscal Year 1986, the Pennsylvania lottery grossed 
$1.3 billion.  Legally, 50 percent of the revenue must be 
paid out in prizes.  Net revenue after costs used to 
benefit senior citizens was $586 million.  Transportation 
programs that benefit from the lottery include a subsidy 
for the elderly for the use of mass transit services in 
general and a 75 percent discount for taxi fares.


-132-

The lottery was enacted after a long public airing of the 
controversial aspects of a lottery. In particular the 
"sins" of gambling, the opportunities for corruption ant 
the participation of the poor was debated. Establishing 
senior citizens as the beneficiaries was the final 
compromise that emerged.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Lottery
For the year ended June 30, 1986, the Arizona lottery 
grossed $121 million with a net of $37 million allocated 
to cities and towns and to the Highway User  Revenue 
Fund.  The population of Texas is approximately five 
times that of Arizona, while the NCTCOG planning area 
accounts for approximately one-fifth of the state's 
population.  Hence, Arizona's net returns can be treated 
as a good estimate of prospective net returns to the 
NCTCOG area. Using that $37 million figure yields:

_____________________________________________________________
                               Revenue in millions of dollars
	                       Current       Increment
			       Level Annual Projected over
       Source of Revenue       (Annual Current 24 years to 2010
                               Total) Level   Low-   High-
			                     Annual Annual
			                       x 24  x 36
______________________________________________________________                                           Revenue in 


Lottery                         ---	37       890     1335
     
Sources

References: Arizona Lottery Annual Report, 1984-85. 
            Arizona Lottery Local Transportation 
            Assistance Fund, Distribution to Cities for 
            Fiscal Year 1985-1986.

	    William H. Inman, "Our Own Money Machine", Texas 
            Business,  March, 1985, 122-124.

            Rice Center, A Guide to Innovative Financing 
            Mechanisms for Mass Transportation - An Update. 
            Final Report (Preliminary) Prepared for Urban Mass 
            Transportation Administration, December, 1985.

	    Texas Comptroller of Public Accounts, "A Texas 
            Lottery?", Fiscal Notes, May, 1986.



-133-

Contacts: Debbie Armstrong, Public Relations Arizona 
	  Lottery 301 East Virginia, Suite 1200 Phoenix, 
	  AZ 85004 602-255-1470

          Richard Doyajian, Financial Analyst
          State of Pennsylvania Budget Office 
          Strawberry Square, Room 733 
          Harrisburg, Penn. 717-787-9793


-134-

		IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES

		MECHANISM (1): ARBITRAGE

			Overview
Definition

Arbitrage is a purchase in one market at a lower price 
and a sale in another market at a higher price of the 
same or equivalent item.  State and local governments 
have had great opportunities for arbitrage because their 
bond issues typically carry lower interest rates than 
federal government or private market securities, because 
of favorable federal tax treatment of interest payments.  
Hence, proceeds from the sale of state and local bonds	can be 
reinvested at higher interest rates.

Example

Toll Road financing in Harris County, Texas. Texas Turnpike 
Authority, Dallas North Tollway.

Financial Results

In financing toll roads in Harris County, Texas to serve 
the Houston metropolitan area, over $500 million in 
revenue bonds were issued.  The revenue was used to 
purchase higher yielding federal government securities 
with the same maturity date as the revenue bonds.  At the 
time, federal securities yielded about one percent more 
in interest than municipal bonds. Thus, the net gain on 
the sale was on the order of $5 million.  The Texas 
Turnpike Authority has also successfully used arbitrage 
in financing the Dallas North Tollway, with a 
considerable build-up in cash reserves the result.  In 
the recent past, arbitrage potential ranged as high as a 
4% differential between interest rates paid by state and 
local agencies and interest rates received.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative Operating under IRS narrowly defined 
  rules, public entities can arbitrage money borrowed at 
  tax-exempt rates and invest it in financial instruments 
  paying higher interest rates.  The rules, which must be 
  strictly followed, as of 1982 allowed reinvestment of 
  bond proceeds for a period of up to 3 years on that 
  portion of proceeds to be used to pay for capital 
  projects; and reinvestment of debt service reserve funds 
  was allowed for the duration of the bonds.  The new 
  federal tax law places a 6 month limit on arbitrage 
  mechanisms; beyond that period, penalties will be 
  imposed.

  Political Bond issues often involve voter referendums.

  Economic The change in the tax law will likely complicate 
  planning and construction scheduling as well as reduce 
  total funds available for toll roads and other activities 
  dependent on arbitrage.


-135-

		IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES

	MECHANISM (2): EXTERNAL CREDIT SUPPORTS

			Overview


Variations: Municipal Bond Insurance, Bank Line of 
Credit, Revenue Bonds backed with a Full 
Faith and Credit Pledge, Bond Pooling

Definition

An external credit support is the use of another entity's 
credit bearing capability to lessen the risk to the bond 
buyer and lower the cost of borrowing for the bond 
issuer.

In order to reduce risk, an entity will seek an external 
mechanism that will assume the debt in case of default.  
Such a mechanism will improve the rating and lower the 
interest cost.  Bond insurance requires a premium while 
other options can be less costly to arrange.

Bond pooling is the process of combining the funding of 
capital projects from several governmental units in one 
bond issue.  The advantage of pooling is that it makes 
the overall package more stable and of less risk to the 
investor.

Example

The Texas Small Business Industrial Development 
Corporation created a $750 million pool to fund 
infrastructure and capital improvements in Texas cities.  
The pool insures that participating Texas cities and 
counties will receive an AAA rating on their bonds 
despite the worsening State economy. (Dallas Morning 
News, July 27, 1986, p.5H)

Financial Results

A letter of credit from an AAA bank can raise a BAA bond 
to an AAA level and lower its interest cost.  The annual 
charge for these services can be in the neighborhood of 
.50 percent of authorized funds.  Municipal Bond 
Insurance can cost anywhere from 0.1 to 2.0 percent of 
the issued amount depending on the degree of risk.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative Arranging an external credit 
   support relationship between public entities may 
   not be permissible by law.

   Political Arranging an external credit support 
   capability requires a reciprocating relationship.  
   Both entities should hold space for the other in 
   their loan portfolios.

   Economic The primary benefit is the reduction of 
   risk facing the individual borrower.  However, some 
   analysts believe that small groups of pooled 
   projects are not better off than individual 
   projects, in terms of bond ratings.  Apparently, 
   unless a major fund is involved, the analysis of 
   the individual projects will prevail in the minds 
   of the ratings service.


-136-

		   IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES

		MECHANISM (33: LEASING OPTIONS

			Overview

Variations: Sale-Leaseback, Safe Harbor Leasing, Lease 
            Purchase,  Leverage Leasing

Definition

The leasing options employ a third party who buys a 
property for use by a public entity and leases it back to 
the public entity.  The lease can be a true lease or a 
financing lease.  A true lease allows the public entity 
to use a privately owned property.  The private owner can 
finance the property with tax-exempt debt, but upon sale 
must sell the property at fair market value.  A version 
of a true lease is a sale - leaseback in which a public 
property is sold to a private owner for lease back to the 
original public owner.  Safe Harbor Leasing is a lease 
form recognized under the Economic Recovery Tax Act which 
allows the sale of privately held tax write-offs to other 
private companies.  A financing lease is a conditional 
sale over time from a private investor to a public 
entity.  This form, also called lease-purchase, requires 
payments be divided into principal and interest 
components.  A version of this is a leveraged lease which 
requires participation of a lender as a third party 
provider of capital to the
lessor.

Example

Industrial revenue bonds; these allow the investor the 
opportunity to buy a property for economic development 
with a tax exempt option and lease the property to 
government or to an industry.

Financial Results
A leasing option could save anywhere from 2 to 4% in 
interest points.  This would convert into an additional 
$20,000 to $40,000 for each one million dollars borrowed. 
Those savings, if obtained annually in perpetuity, would 
be worth $200,000 to $400,000 if capitalized at 10 
percent.

Major Issues

  Legal/Administrative The tax law governing these 
  options has changed three times in the last five 
  years with the newest and most restrictive tax law 
  approved for implementation as of 1987.  The effect 
  of the new law is to raise interest rates that 
  governments must pay and to impose a ceiling on the 
  amounts of bonds that may be issued under this 
  option.

  Political Some political actors regard the 
  combination of private and public financial means 
  as an inappropriate role for government.

  Economic All of these options offer the lessor a 
  number of options for earning tax-exempt interest, 
  plus claiming depreciation and tax investment 
  credits.


-137-

			IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES

	MECHANISM (4): STANDARD OR "VANILLA FOLDER" BOND

				Overview

Variations: General Obligation Bonds, Revenue Bonds

Definition

General Obligation Bonds are secured with the "good faith 
and credit" of the local government.  This means that the 
government will guarantee the payment of the bond with 
the pledge to use its taxing capability.  If the 
government has a limitation imposed by the state or its 
people through referendum, the ability to guarantee 
repayment is correspondingly limited.  Such limitations 
often lower the credit of the government issuing the 
bonds.

A revenue bond is guaranteed by the fees to be gained by 
the proposed governmental venture enterprise.  Since it 
is a venture enterprise, its risk is considered higher by 
investors, and correspondingly, a higher interest rate 
has to be charged.  The amount depends on the types of 
venture for which the bond is to be used.

Both bonds are considered the standards in the bond 
industry. Because of this status, they have gained the 
in-house name of "Vanilla Folder" bonds.

Financial Results

The value of savings of a half percent for a 20 year bond 
with semiannual payments is $5,125 for each one million 
dollars borrowed; capitalizing the savings at 10% yields 
a net value of $51,250.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative The state gives the right to a 
   local entity to issue debt. This debt authorization 
   can restrict the type of debt incurred.  A specific 
   authorization must exist for general obligation 
   bonds to be used. For tollway authorities, revenue 
   bonds are the standard means with which to incur 
   debt.  The new federal tax law places special tests 
   and restrictions on the use of these bonds.

   Political General obligation bonds can raise the 
   rate of property assessment for a community.  This 
   is a sensitive issue for most communities.

   Economic A general obligation bond is considered 
   the lowest risk bond in which to invest.  It 
   carries the lowest cost for the issuer.  A 
   transportation related bond is usually a quarter to 
   a half percent less in interest rate if it is a 
   general obligation bond rather than a revenue bond.


-138-

			IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES
		MECHANISM (5): INNOVATIVE BOND ISSUES
				Overview

Variation: Original Issue Discount Bonds, Zero Coupon Bonds

Definition

An Innovative Bond Issue is a bond constructed to attract 
investors who usually do not buy bonds.  In order to do this a 
number of unusual discountor coupon related features are added 
to the bond.

An Original Issue Discount Bond (OID) is a long term bond 
offered at a rate of interest substantially less than 
prevailing rates.  The bond is originally sold at a price 
considerably less than its stated (or par) value so that 
a capital gain is created, which is given favorable 
treatment by the tax laws.

Zero coupon bonds (ZCBs) are bonds sold without coupons, 
which is another term for interest bearing progress 
payments. ZCBs are sold at prices substantially below 
their face value, and upon maturity, the issuer pays the 
face value of the bond in one lump sum.  The difference 
between the bond's purchase price and its value at 
maturity provides a yield that is competitive with other 
investments in the marketplace.  The IRS considers the 
discount to be interest income and tax-exempt for bonds 
issued by public entity.  (DOT-1-82-53, p.39)

Examples

1981 New Jersey Health Care Facility Financing Authority 
Bonds (OID), and 1982 Massachusetts Bay Transportation 
Authority General Transportation System Bonds (ZCB).

Financial Results

Depending on the structure of the overall issue, the cost 
of raising funds using OIDs and ZCBs could range from 0.5 
to 2.0 percent less in interest costs than if traditional 
bonds are used.

Major Issues

   Legal/Administrative The recent tax laws may impede 
   the use of innovative bond issues.

   Political Few political problems are apparent in 
   the literature on the topic.

   Economic Reduction in preferential tax treatment of 
   capital gains should reduce the attractiveness of 
   this form of bonds.


-139-

			IX. BORROWING STRATEGIES

				Detail

General Information

Traditionally, government securities are debt obligations 
with fixed maturities and fixed interest rates.  Instead 
of seeking a long term loan from a bank, a municipality 
offers its long term debt in the form of bonds. These 
debt instruments have a vocabulary all their own.  For 
example, a coupon, which is a component of some bonds, 
can be exchanged for an interest payment due on a 
specific date, usually at semiannual intervals.  A call 
option allows the bond issuer to call in the bond for 
payment of the principle prior to its stated maturity 
date.  A put option allows the bond bearer to submit the 
bond for payment of principal prior to its maturity date.

The two major ways of issuing bonded debt are through the 
use of General Obligation Bonds and Revenue Bonds.  
General Obligation Bonds are sold with a pledge to use 
the general taxing power of the jurisdiction to guarantee 
the repayment of the bonds.  Usually this means that the 
property tax or some other tax will be used to generate 
repayment funds.  These bonds carry the lowest interest 
rates that are offered on municipal bonds.  In recent 
years, limitations on the use of the property tax to 
support public services has resulted in higher interest 
costs to the municipality due to a perception that the 
risk on general obligation bonds has increased.

Revenue Bonds are instruments whose principal and 
interest are payable exclusively from the revenue of 
publicly owned enterprises.  In addition to a pledge of 
revenues, such bonds sometimes contain a mortgage on the 
enterprise's property.  Revenue bonds typically carry a 
higher interest rate than general obligation bonds, 
usually a minimum of a half percentage point higher for 
comparably rated AAA entities.


-140-

What is creative financing? During the recently ended 
period of abnormally high interest rates many creative 
alternative mechanism of debt finance were developed.  
Borrowing options such as lease-purchase and interest 
arbitrage received considerable attention.  Peterson and 
Hough cite four motivations in this shift to "creative 
financing": (1) efforts to shift interest rate risk from 
the investor to the borrower; (2) efforts to enhance the 
credit worthiness of borrowers by shifting credit-related 
risks to third parties; (3) actions that increase the 
types of returns available beyond regular receipt of 
interest income payments, and (4) instrument designs that 
appeal to the needs of specialized investor groups.

Despite considerable interest in developing borrowing 
strategies geared to one or more of these motivations, 
the actual impact is debatable.  Experts in the field 
question the profitability of some of these new options. 
Furthermore and most important, the federal tax bill of 
1986 has clouded the legality and desirability of many of 
these new options.  Experts are urging municipalities to 
return to more traditional financing methods using 
general obligation and revenue bonds.

How is a credit rating established? A credit rating is 
set by a ratings service, of which there are two.  
Standard and Poors rates credit worthiness for municipal 
bonds on a scale that ranges from AAA to D. Moody's 
Investor Service uses an Aaa to C rating.  Both rating 
systems reflect degree of risk. Moody's ratings, for 
example, can be summarized as follows:


-141-

Aaa: Best investment prospects
Aa : High quality
A  : Upper medium grade with many favorable attributes

Baa: Medium grade
Ba : Several speculative elements
B  : Lacks characteristics of a desirable investment

Caa: Of poor standing, may be in default
Ca : Speculative in a high degree
C  : Extremely poor prospects

Generally, as the financial health of both the government 
and its local economy improves, the credit rating 
improves.  If the local economy declines, the potential 
obligations of the local government increase at the same 
time that corresponding potential revenues contract.

The actual interest rate is the product of two factors.  
One factor is the
credit rating, which is an index of the risk of defaults, 
and the other is the type of bond offered.  The more 
attractive the bond, the lower the interest rate.  
General obligation bonds are generally considered more 
attractive than revenue bonds.  Attractiveness can be 
further increased by adding a "put" option (sometimes 
called a demand option) and a regular payment structure.

Innovations in creative financing have included a number 
of mechanisms which lower the risk to the investor.  One 
such innovation is municipal bond insurance  which 
insures against default.  A second is a bank line of 
credit which provides a source of funds for the 
municipality's liquidity.  Such a device can be useful 
when obligations are increasing at financially difficult 
times.  A third is a mechanism called bond pooling, which 
combines the funding of capital projects from several 
governmental units into one issue so that risk can be 
spread and


-142-

the rating improved.  A fourth is the issuance of revenue 
bonds guaranteed by the general taxing power of the 
municipality if it turns out that the enterprise revenues 
are insufficient to pay the bonds.

How is a bond issued? Once a municipality has defined the 
bond issue, it must seek a buyer.  This is usually done 
through a dealer who buys and sells bonds.  The dealer 
can take a long position on the bond which means that he 
owns it, or a short position which means that he has 
agreed to sell and deliver bonds not yet owned by him.

Bonds are usually offered by competitive sale to 
institutional investors.  In recent years, an increasing 
number of issues have been offered by negotiation, which 
means that potential investors were identified and the 
interest rate negotiated with them.

The total coat of a bond issue is composed of the 
interest cost, the cost to float the bond, and the cost 
of debt service.  Two elements compose the flotation 
cost.  The first is the dealer's spread which is the 
difference between his buying price and his selling price 
for the bond issue. The second is the marketing cost of 
the issue.  A key component of the marketing cost is the 
advertising required to attract investors.

This cost should not be confused with the marketing 
efforts of the municipality to the rating service. Some 
municipalities, such as the City of Richardson, have 
invested considerable staff expenses in developing media 
and supporting materials for presentation to the rating 
service. Such efforts have resulted in higher ratings and 
lower interest costs. 


-143-

The trend in innovative financing During the period of 
high interest rates
alternative mechanisms were developed to offer 
municipalities additional tools with which to secure 
additional capital.  A key factor in the development of 
these options is the use of tax exempt status to attract 
additional investors.  Tax exemption increases the 
after-tax return of these financial instruments.  In 
recent years, the use of tax exemption in these new 
alternatives has been cut back by Federal legislation.  
Some of the new options that have been developed include 
tax exempt industrial bonds, lease-purchase arrangement, 
and interest arbitrage.

Payment from borrowed funds vs. operating funds A highway 
or other capital
project has costs which can be paid out of borrowed funds 
such as bonded debt or out of normal operating revenue 
which will reduce the amount of required borrowed funds.  
Tasks such as preliminary planning, real property rental, 
protective services, preparation for opening, and general 
administrative services are functions that should be 
accounted for as costs to a capital project but are also 
costs that can be paid for out of general operating 
revenue.  Such a move can reduce the funded debt needed 
to support a project by as much as l0% (Moak, p. 156).

Cash flow and interest arbitrage By delaying the payment 
of obligations for reasonable periods of time, the return 
on short term invested funds may be increased.  When 
major loans are involved, short term investment can yield 
substantial returns. Such a practice is referred to as 
interest arbitrage.


-144-
	
Interest arbitrage is the process of privately investing 
funds borrowed at low interest rates in financial 
instruments that return a higher rate of interest.  The 
revenue potential is dependent upon the differential 
between the municipal lending rate and the market rate, 
usually around 3-4%, which can generate  significant 
amounts of revenue.  For example, if $60 million is 
borrowed at 8.5% by a public institution and half of the 
money is not needed for three years, the public 
institution has usually been able to reinvest the unused 
$30 million at 12% for three years.  The net (after 
payment of municipal interest) returns to the public 
institution are more than $1 million.  

The Texas Turnpike Authority, which is extending the 
North Dallas Tollway, is investing its municipal bond 
proceeds in financial instruments paying market rates of 
interest, and has shown a considerable net return from 
the action.  Return on investment has recently run around 
$10 million annually, although this figure is likely to 
be reduced as investment funds are employed to pay for 
construction (conversation with Mr. Harry Kabler).

Significant legal restrictions on the use of interest 
arbitrage has been imposed in recent years.  Most 
recently, new federal tax legislation will put a six 
month limit on arbitrage mechanisms.  Beyond that limit, 
penalties will be imposed.  Thus, the investment period 
will be shortened from the previous limit of three years 
to sex months as of 1987.  This should complicate highway 
planning and the scheduling of contraction.

Potential for Increased Revenue, Borrowing Strategies
In the recent past, as much as 4% of cost could be saved 
by arbitrage and related mechanisms.  However, the new federal 
tax law will likely limit gains to


-145-

a maximum of approximately l%.  Revenue implications for 
those cases and for  type of bond employed are shown in 
the following fiat.  Increments are calculated in terms 
of savings per million dollars, both annually and over 
the 24 year period, 1986-2010. Hence, in this case, there 
is no distinction between high and low cases.

______________________________________________________________			                              
                                 Revenue in millions of dollars
			          Current      Increment
Source of Revenue:                  Level   Annual    Projected
Borrowing Strategies               (Annual  Current   Over 
                                   Total)   Level    24 years
                                                     to 2010
                                                       Annual
                                                         x 24
_____________________________________________________________

Arbitrage and related mechanisms
         1% Cost Saving
NCTCOG "Mobility 2000" shortfall- 
  $6 billion 0r $250 million per 
  year over 24 year period          ---     2.5       60
		
Recent annual highway 
  construction levels in DFW area 
  - about 200 million per year-    
   if all accounted for by bonds   
   financing                       ---        2       48


  	4% Cost Saving
If return to 4% savings rate -
NCTCOG "Mobility 2000" shortfall  ---        10      240
	
Recent Annual highway construction
	in DFW area               ---         8      192
		
Use of general obligation bonds
 rather than revenue bonds
       (1/2% Cost Savings)
NCTCOG "Mobility 2000" shortfall  ---       1.25       30
		
Recent annual highway construction
 in DFW are                      ---           1       24
	

-146-

Sources

References

Lennex L. Moak, Municipal Bonds; Planning, Sale & 
Administration, Chicago, Illinois: Municipal Finance 
Officers Association, 1982, 405 pp.

John E. Peterson and Wesley C. Hough, Creative Capital 
Financing For State and Local Governments, Chicago, 
Illinois: Municipal Finance Officers Association, 1983, 
256 pp.

Rice Center, A Guide to Innovative Financing Mechanisms 
For Mass Transportation, Prepared for Office of Planning 
Assistance, Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D.C., Dec., 1982 (DOT-1-82-53).

Contact 
Harry Kabler, Texas Turnpike Authority, 214-263-1964.


	APPENDIX HIGHWAY FINANCE EXPERIENCE IN CALIFORNIA


			APPENDIX

	HIGHWAY FINANCE EXPERIENCE IN CALIFORNIA

California is often viewed as a trend-setter.  
Developments in the state are perceived as portents of 
things to come elsewhere.

California currently is faced with a significant 
strategic problem.1   It has a highway system with traffic 
usage near capacity.  It has a political culture that is 
highly sensitive to environmentalists and "no-growth" 
advocates.  It has had significant limitations placed on 
its capacity to raise revenue, a governor opposed to 
raising taxes2, and a highway department apparently not 
very interested in innovation.3  Under these conditions a 
number of local actions have occurred in response, under 
three main headings: (1) developer impact fees, (2) 
increased use of local sales taxes for transportation and 
(3) traffic system management plans (TSMs).  The TSMs are 
organized community efforts to reduce the

flow of automobiles into an urban center.  They include 
car pooling, buses, parking fees, and incentives for not 
bringing automobiles into the city.

There seems to be a rough relationship between the state 
of a community's development and the type of highway 
financing device that it emphasizes.  If a community is 
fast-growing, it stresses impact fees.  If a community is 
slow growing, it is more apt to levy additional sales 
taxes for highway improvement.  Finally, reliance on TSMs 
may well imply that a community is approaching the limits 
of its growth.

Because California's experience in highway finance seemed 
of particular interest in this project, a detailed 
investigation of its experience was carried out, both by 
field interviews and literature review, and is reported 
in this


-148-

appendix.  The discussion is organized geographically, 
beginning with Orange County in the South, then 
considering the City of Los Angeles and finally 
concluding with the Bay Area in the North.

Orange County

Orange County has been one of the fastest growing areas 
in the nation. Located to the southeast of Los Angeles 
County, most of its growth in the 1960's was the result 
of people buying homes within commuting distance of Los 
Angeles.  The  main routes for the Los Angeles commute 
were the Santa Ana Freeway, a corridor directly to the 
heart of the city, and the San Diego Freeway; a route 
around the south side of the city.

Orange County has concentrated on developing its 
educational and high technology industries, and its own 
economy has grown at a rapid rate since the mid 1970's.  
It is now part of an extensive corridor of business and 
residential development from Los Angeles to San Diego.  
To accommodate this growth, Orange County must expand its 
highway capacity.  Its County planners appear well fitted 
to this task, for they have a statewide reputation as 
being the most aggressive group investigating alternative 
means of financing transportation.  In addition, the area 
is dominated by a single developer, the Irvine Company, 
which has been a leader in developing entire communities 
with green belts, activity centers, and reserved areas 
for shopping, working, and social-recreation activities.  
The large scale of the Irvine Company operation appears 
conducive to joint public private financing of highways.

Transportation is the primary concern of Orange County 
residents, on the basis of a number of polls, but the 
concern is not shared at the state level.4    Consequently, 
the County is planning a number of highway developments 
on its own initiative.  Each will be described, in turn.


-149-

Three New Freeways. The County is seeking to develop 
three new freeways.5 The first is the San Jonquin Freeway 
which would parallel the San Diego freeway west of Irvine 
and Newport Beach.  The area is undeveloped.  The Irvine 
Company wishes to develop it and wants a freeway within 
it to facilitate development.  The second freeway planned 
is the Foothill Freeway, which would serve another 
currently undeveloped area in the northern foothills of 
the County.  It is anticipated that residential 
communities will expand into that area, generating a need 
for a new freeway parallel to the Santa Ana freeway, 
which is currently congested for eight hours a day.  A 
planned third freeway, the Eastern Freeway, would run 
north and south from the northern Orange County area of 
Fullerton and Yorba Linda, into the southern area of 
Irvine.

Two community based Joint Powers Authorities have been 
established to build the freeways.  One Authority is 
responsible for the development of both the Foothill  and 
Eastern freeways, while the other is responsible for the 
San Joaquin Freeway.  Membership on the governing boards 
of the authorities will consist of representatives of the 
involved city governments, the Orange County Planning 
Commission and the Orange County Board of Supervisors.

It has been estimated that 40% of the cost of these 
freeways will be supported by developer fees.  The major 
developer, the Irvine Company, will likely pass the cost 
on to its customers.  It is hoped that the remaining 
funds needed will come from the federal government.  
Should federal funds not be forthcoming, then other 
options being considered include revenue from the 
property tax and highway tolls.  The property tax 
allocation would be difficult to come by, but a cost 
shifting strategy has been formulated whereby some 
existing educational


-150-

costs would be absorbed by the state, allowing an 
increased investment in transportation by as much as $25 
million per year.  The serious consideration of toll 
roads marks a break with past attitudes, for the use of 
tolls has been limited to bridges in California.6

The Golden Triangle of Orange County.  High growth places 
often have an area designated as a golden triangle.  
Orange County is no exception, its golden triangle being 
bounded by the Santa Ana, San Diego and Laguna Freeways.  
The area so defined is surrounded by high technology and 
other industrial developments.  A major shopping center 
and office complex is planned for the area, with total 
transportation costs to be absorbed by the Irvine 
Company.  This will include the construction of arterial 
roads and arterial-freeway connections.7

The City of Irvine Developer Impact Fee. The City of 
Irvine is the home of Orange County Airport, which is a 
regional airport with limited capacity. The surrounding 
area was intended to be a low profile industrial and 
commercial area.  Two story office buildings and hotels 
were built until the early 1980's.  Soon after the turn 
of the decade, however, the area surrounding the airport 
began more intensive development.  New buildings within a 
mile of the airport expanded from 2 stories to ten 
stories.  The City of Irvine responded by designating an 
area surrounding the airport, about one mile in extent, 
as an impact area.  Any development now occurring in the 
area must pay the City a $6 per square foot charge as a 
traffic impact fee.  The revenue collected pays for 
enlarged streets, improved intersections, and freeway 
access improvements.8

The Huntington Beach Super Street Demonstration Project.  
Beach Boulevard is a major six-lane arterial which runs 
north and south through Orange and Los Angeles Counties.  
The corridor was once on the state's transportation plan 
for


-151-

conversion into a freeway.  It is congested to the point 
that 15 out of 40 intersections operate at unacceptable 
levels of traffic.  By 2005, this figure is expected to 
rise to 24 out of 40, if no changes occur.  A proposed 
set of changes would create a blend of freeway and 
arterial by expanding of lanes, timing of lights and 
restriping.  A key point of interest here is that the 
proposal involves the cooperation of 10 separate 
jurisdictions.9

Review of the Traffic System Management Plan Options. 
County planners are considering the possibility of 
developing a traffic management plan which would help 
alleviate the need for transportation investment.  
Businesses would be encouraged by common interest or by 
municipal ordinance to adopt flex-time scheduling, 
car-pooling, and increased bus ridership.  This option is 
under study but has not been enforced.10

Service Authority for Freeway Emergencies. Los Angeles 
County maintains a system of phone boxes alongside its 
freeways.  These phones are used by motorists who need 
service or other assistance.  Orange County has opted to 
develop such a system for its freeways.  What is 
innovative is the methodology it has adopted to finance 
such a system, for Orange County has secured 
authorization from the State to impose an additional $1 
on the automobile registration fee.  The law which 
permits this could be used by other counties should they 
elect to build a similar system. 11

City of Los Angeles
The innovative devices that Los Angeles is adopting 
center around two approaches.  The first is an impact fee 
approach called "mitigation by ordinance."  The second is 
an extensive use of traffic system management techniques 
by the Los Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency.  The 
impact fee


-152-

areas are located in growth centers outside of the 
downtown area, while the traffic system management plan 
applies to the central downtown area.  Los Angeles City’s 
Mitigation by Ordinance.  The City of Los Angeles has 
been undergoing evolutionary change in terms of (1) the 
process of new development approval, and (2) the 
economics of transportation development. Under the first 
change, the zoning approval process for commercial 
development has been changed from what has been known as 
"ministerial approval" to an approach referred to as 
"discretionary approval."  The ministerial approach is 
simply the automatic approval of a zoning application if 
it fits into the overall land use plan for the area 
regardless of such factors as the additional traffic 
impact that the development will cause.  In contrast, a 
discretionary system requires the City’s planning staff 
to examine all zoning applications of a commercial nature 
for traffic and related impacts regardless of implied 
approval in the zoning system.12

The City Council has designated four impact areas in 
separate ordinances. These are the Century City 
development area, the Coastal development area, the West 
Wilshire area, and the Ventura development area.  The 
four areas were created in a similar manner but have 
different impact fees.

The public policy approach that the City used to create 
the four impact areas is called the "Citywide 
Transportation Impact Mitigation Procedural Ordinance."13    
This ordinance has two major features.  First, it directs 
the Planning Department to recommend to the City Council 
those areas which require a Transportation Impact Area 
designation.  There are areas where development could 
raise the ratio of actual traffic volume on the areas 
streets and highways to 0.81 or higher of their capacity.  
The Planning Department then shall present to the Council 
an Interim Control Ordinance, which sets forth the 
conditions for


-153-

interim review procedures for development approval.  
Several Interim Control Ordinance's place moratoria on 
development in their respective impact areas and require 
the planning staff to develop traffic studies in 
preparation of Specific Plans.  Second, the Council then will 
direct the planning staff to develop a Transportation Specific
Plan which includes a list of specific transportation 
improvements, transit projects and/or trip reduction measures, 
transportation assessment fees, exemptions, and other 
relevant procedures.

The first specific plan to be approved was the Century 
City Specific Plan. Century City is a major development 
of high rise office buildings and entertainment complexes 
within a nine block area of Los Angeles.  The plan calls 
for a list of traffic improvements and a procedure for 
prorating the cost of the improvements back to the 
developers.14    

The second Specific Plan to be approved was the Coastal 
Ordinance which set forth an impact fee of $2,010 per 
peak hour trip generated.  The ordinance and its impact 
fee applies to a substantial area from the Los Angeles 
International area north through Westchester - Playa Del 
Rey and West from the San Diego Freeway to the beach. 
This approach differs from the prorate approach in that 
it calculates the total number of peak hour trips that 
all development in the impact area should generate. The 
total costs of the traffic improvements for the area are 
divided by the total number of peak hour trips.  The 
result is an impact fee which is charged to the 
developer. The fee, like the prorate approach, places the 
burden of traffic mitigation on the developer.15

The third Specific Plan to be approved was the Westwood 
plan.  This plan applies to a six block area that runs 
along Wilshire Boulevard just south of the University of 
California, Los Angeles.  It also uses an impact fee 
approach.  The basic fee is $5,650 per peak hour trip 
generated.16


-154-

The fourth area is being developed under an interim 
control ordinance.  The Ventura impact area is a several 
mile corridor running along Ventura Boulevard through the 
communities of Encino, Sherman Oaks, Tarzana, and 
Woodland Hills.   A specific plan and a specific impact 
fee is being considered.17

There is a significant aspect of the Citywide 
Transportation Mitigation Ordinance that applies to 
another major transportation undertaking in Los Angeles.  
The Ordinance includes provisions for transportation 
system management plans sponsored by redevelopment 
agencies.  There is a significant effort under way 
sponsored by the Los Angeles Community Redevelopment 
Agency, which will  now be discussed.

LACRA Traffic System Management Plan. The Los Angeles 
Community Redevelopment Agency (LACRA), an agency of the 
City of Los Angeles, covers a downtown triangular area 
bordered by the Harbor Freeway on the west, the Santa 
Monica Freeway on the south, and Alameda Boulevard on the 
east.  The redevelopment agency manages a traffic system 
management plan for the downtown area under the legal 
auspices of the Citywide Transportation Mitigation 
Ordinance.18

The perception in downtown Los Angeles is that as soon as 
the new 20 mile, $2 billion Century Freeway is completed, 
the capacity of the freeway system will be set for the 
foreseeable future.  The only available option for the 
future is to reduce the amount of traffic coming into the 
area.  This can be accomplished without curtailing 
commercial growth with the aid of a traffic system 
management plan.

The LACRA TSM plan requires a project owner to implement 
an employee rideshare program.  The intent of the program 
is to enroll 60% of the project's population in 
ridesharing programs, including car pooling, shuttles, 
buses, and flex time.


-155-

An important requirement of the program is that the 
project owner must maintain a "Commuter Transportation 
Coordinator" on site.  The rideshare program also carries 
significant penalties for failing to fulfill its terms.19   
A project owner can be assessed an amount of money for 
the purchase of shuttle vans.  The exact amount of the 
assessment is calculated from the number of seats that 
the project would draw from a shuttle fleet if the 
project were participating in a rideshare program.  The 
impact of the program design is to eliminate any 
incentive for the project owner not to participate.  This 
is accomplished by making the investment the same 
regardless of the option the owner pursues.  The 
advantage the owner obtains for participating is that he 
can keep the resources under his control and invest them 
in a manner moat beneficial to his employees.

The traffic system management plan is designed to 
complement the freeway system, the traffic impact areas, 
and the new rail system that Los Angeles is building.  
That latter system is being financed with the use of a 
variety of methods.  One of them is a benefit assessment 
district.

Metro Rail Benefit Assessment Districts.  Metro Rail is a 
$3.2 billion, 18.6 mile rail subway being built by the 
Southern California Rapid Transit District (SCRTD).  The 
subway will link downtown Los Angeles with Hollywood and 
with the San Fernando Valley.  The metro rail financial 
plan calls for $170 million to be raised through benefit 
assessment districts.20

Two benefit assessment districts have been established to 
date.  Their boundaries essentially consist of an 0.5 
mile radius around the planned metro rail stations.  The 
rate of assessment ranges from 30 cents to 42 cents per 
square foot of gross building area per year, depending on 
the bond repayment schedule.  This method of financing is 
supplemented by Federal aid, and by a local sales tax.


-156-

The Bay Area

San Francisco Bay Area was one of the high growth areas 
of the 60's and 70's owing to the advent of 
micro-electronic related industries.  The physical plant 
of the commercial and residential communities of the area 
has matured and there seems to be 8 limited potential for 
expansion.  The new areas of growth are in the cities of 
Contra Costa County which are inland and fast becoming a 
major center of office and commercial development.  
Because the area is in a mature phase of development, the 
ability of community leaders to assign transportation 
improvement costs to developers is extremely limited.

The Bay area has four centers of transportation activity.  
Santa Clara County is expanding its freeway system with 
an 0.5 cent sales tax and its transit system with an 
additional 0.5 cent sales tax.  The City of San Francisco 
is planning steady levels of commercial growth with no 
planned expansion of the traffic system by relying on an 
extensive transportation system management plan.  The 
City of Pleasanton is undergoing rapid expansion but has 
designed a transportation system management plan as a 
main strategy for accommodating that growth.21    Finally, 
Northern California is operating an extensive transit 
system with BART (Bay Area Rapid Transit) and the several 
bus companies that serve the area.

Santa Clara County

Santa Clara County rests at the southern end of San 
Francisco Bay and contains the cities of Santa Clara and 
San Jose.  The County has always had a high regard for 
transportation.  It has had a good political leadership 
supplying transportation as a necessary component to 
support the high technology industry that has moved to 
the area.  This leaderahip has resulted in a separate 
district for the bus company and the County's own freeway 
system.22     The County passed a


-157-

bond issue in 1961 to build eight expressways.  The 
expressway concept was innovative, consisting of a six or 
eight lane major arterial with very few traffic lights or 
other interferences.  It seems somewhat similar to the 
Orange County SuperStreet concept.


Santa Clara County currently employs two voter approved 
sales tax initiatives to support transit projects.  The 
first of these initiatives is a bond issue to expand or 
build three freeways.  The first freeway project is a 
widening of a 30 mile section of US 101, the main highway 
to use when traveling up the California Coast.  The 
widening consists of the addition of high occupancy 
vehicle (HOV) lanes and three new interchanges.  The 
second project is a conversion of State Highway 237.  The 
project consists of the conversion of a six lane arterial 
with five traffic lights to a freeway with interchanges 
in place of lights.  The third project is the 
construction of a 20 mile freeway along State Route 85, 
which was set aside for this purpose 35 years ago.  The 
freeway would be a six lane freeway with two of those 
lanes dedicated to HOV purposes.
	
The second 0.5 cent sales tax was approved in 1976 
before the Jarvis-Gann Proposition 13 initiative was 
adopted.  This tax is used to support a number of 
different transit projects from buses to light rail.  For 
example, 15 to 20% of the bus system is subsidized by the 
tax.  There are a number of other initiatives being 
pursued. 

One initiative is a corridor analysis to extend BART 12 
miles into the County.  Should the project be built, it 
would require Federal assistance. The state and local 
share would be in excess of $500 million if the project 
eventually is built.


-158-

A second initiative is a $50 million commitment to extend 
the CalTrain.  This is a commuter train that rune from 
downtown San Francisco into San Jose.  Included in the 
project are two additional stations.

A third initiative is a $65 million project to add HOV 
lanes to locally financed expressways.  These lanes would 
be used for buses.  The possibility exists for car and 
van pools to use these lanes.  However, the fact that the 
funding source is dedicated to transit purposes 
complicates the use of these lanes for car pooling.  This 
is a legal question that will have to be resolved in the 
courts.

San Francisco The City of San Francisco has adopted a 
policy, by ordinance, that the capacity of the traffic 
system shall be fixed for essentially the foreseeable 
future.  No new freeways will be built in the City or to 
the City.  Despite this static situation, the City's 
commercial plan will require an increase in 
transportation capacity.  The City has made a policy 
decision to use a transportation system management plan 
to accommodate this growth that will result in a 65-70% 
increase in alternative forms of transportation.23

The City is currently promoting two complementary 
policies.  The first is a policy of creating incentives 
for people to use transit and other alternative forms of 
transportation.  This is done by having project owners 
participate in the coordination of TSM projects.  The 
other is to pursue a series of disincentives for people 
to use their automobiles in the City. This is done by 
purposely creating a shortage in the supply of parking 
facilities.  New commercial development must pay both a 
traffic impact fee and participate in a transportation 
system management plan.  The impact fee is intended to 
reimburse the City for the traffic mitigations that it 
has to undertake because


-l59-

of the development.  The impact fee amount is a one-time 
charge of $5.00 per square foot of the development's space.  
The TSM is an extensive process that is very similar in concept
and structure to that of the Los Angeles CRA.

The City's planning staff approves commercial buildings 
with a unique standard for parking.  Any other city 
without the space and traffic problems of San Francisco 
would require a high ratio of parking spaces to the 
project's employees.  In San Francisco, a development 
which would normally have a 2,000 space garage would be 
approved with a 200 space garage.  Many of these spaces 
are dedicated to vans, shuttles, car pools, and visitor 
parking.  The economic impact of this city requirement is 
that it helps to support monthly parking rates of $250 
per car.  This contributes to the "disincentive" approach 
the City has in transportation policy.


-160-
APPENDIX FOOTNOTES

 1. Theme suggested by Dr. William Garrison, Professor of 
    Civil Engineering, University of California, Berkeley 
    in a personal interview, August 19, 1986.

 2. Personal interview with Dr. Thomas Fortune, Public 
    Affairs Officer, Orange County Transportation 
    Commission, August 15, 1986.

 3. Ibid.

 4. Ibid.

 5. Personal interview with Dr. Genevieve Juiliano, 
    Research Specialist and Assistant to the Director, 
    Institute of Transportation Studies, University of 
    California, Irvine, August 12, 1986.

 6. "Findings: Toll Road Feasibility Study, 
     Foothill/Eastern Transportation Corridors". Orange 
     County Transportation Commission, June, 1986.

 7. Personal interview with Mr. Craig Neusteedler, 
    A.I.C.P., Senior Transportation Analyst, City of 
    Irvine, California, August 13, 1986.

 8. Ibid.

 9.  Orange County Transportation Commission, 
     SuperStreets Demonstration,  Project, April, 1986.

10. Orange County Transportation Commission, "Traffic 
    Reduction Incentives Program for Orange County, 
    Project Description and Work Program", August 1986. 

11. Arthur Young Consultants, "Report to the Orange 
    County Transportation Commission on a Service Authority 
    for Freeway Emergencies" (SAFE),  January, 1986.

12. Personal interview with Dr. Philip M. Aker, Supervising 
    Transportation Planner I, and Michael J. Uyeno, 
    Transportation Engineering Associate,  Department of 
    Transportation, City of Los Angeles, August, 14 1986.

13. City of Los Angeles, "Citywide Transportation Mitigation 
    Procedural Ordinance," City of Los Angeles, July 17, 1986.

14. "Century City North Specific Plan," City of Los 
    Angeles Ordinance No. 156,122.

15. "Coastal Transportation Corridor Specific Plan," City 
    of Los Angeles Ordinance No. 160,394.

16. Westwood Regional Center Interim Traffic Mitigation 
    Ordinance No. 159,725, and interview with Mr. Philip 
    Aker and Mr. Michael Uyeno, August, 14, 1986.

17. Ventura Boulevard Interim Traffic Mitigation 
    Ordinance, City of Los Angeles Ordinance No. 
   160,406.


-161-

18. Personal interview with Ma. Ellen Gelbard and Dr. 
    Patrick Roche, Transportation Planning Associates, 
    Los Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency of the 
    City of Loa Angeles, August 14, 1986.

19. City of Loa Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency 
    "Transportation System Management (TSM) Rideshare 
    Agreement for Downtown Los Angeles," June 21, 1985.

20. Richard Wilacn, "Loa Angeles Metro Rail Benefit 
    Assessment: Analyzing Impacts on Real Estate Economics," 
    City of Los Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency, 
    December, 1985.

21. "Summary and Evaluation of Transportation Management 
     Program Option", Crain and Associates, Inc., Loa 
     Angeles, California, April, 1986.

22. Personal interview with Mr. David Minister, 
    Professional Engineer, Manager of Project 
    Development, Transportation Agency, County of Santa 
    Clara, August, 18, 1986.

23. Personal interviews with Mr. Chi Hain Shao, 
    Transportation Section Head, Department of City 
    Planning, City and County of San Francisco, August 
    18, 1986.


BIBLIOGRAPHY


-162-

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Sandra Albrecht, 1985 Dallas/Fort Worth Shopping Center 
Survey, Henry S. Miller Co. Realtors, Dallas, Texas, 
1985.

American Association of State Highway and Transportation 
Officials, AASHTO Report: A Study on Future Directions of 
Public Transportation in the United States, Washington, 
D.C., Feb. 22, 1985.

American Association of State Highway Officials, AASHTO 
Report: A New Focus for America's Highways: 
Recommendations on the Federal-Aid Program, Washington, 
D.C., April, 1985.

Arizona Lottery Annual Report, 1984-85.

Arizona Lottery Local Transportation Assistance Fund, 
Distribution to Cities for Fiscal Year 1985-1986.

Black's Guide, Inc., Black's Office Leasing Guide, Fall 
86, Dallas, Texas, 1986.

City of Farmers Branch, Texas, Improvement Ordinances for 
the East Side Improvement District: 
	# 1430: Platting and Subdivision of Land, Feb., 1983 
	# 1439: Water and Sewer Line Improvements, May, 1983 
	# 1440: Water and Sewer Line Improvements, June, 1983 
	# 1526: Paving Improvements, Nov., 1984 
	# 1528: Paving Improvements, Nov., 1984

City of Denver, Colorado, Documents on 16th Street Mall:
  Ordinance # 575, Series of 1983, Creation of 
     District for 16th Street  Pedestrian and Transit Mall.
  Ordinance # 736, Series of 1983, Assessing Annual 
     Costs of Mall
  Ordinance # 662, Series of 1984, Assessing Annual 
     Costs of Mall
  Amendatory Cooperation Agreement, 1984, with "Downtown 
     Denver, Inc.  (DDI)"
  Proposed Contract, Continuing operation of Mall, 
     with DDI, March 6, 1986.

City of Escondido, California, "Ground Lease Development 
Rights", Jan. 1981.

City of Los Angeles, California
   Century City North Specific Plan, Ordinance No. 156,122.
   Westwood Regional Center Interim Traffic Mitigation 
     Ordinance, Ordinance No. 159, 725.
  Coastal Transportation Corridor Specific Plan, 
     Ordinance No. 160,394.
  Ventura Boulevard Interim Traffic Litigation 
      Ordinance, Ordinance No. 160,406.
  Citywide Transportation Impact Litigation 
      Procedural Ordinance, July 17, 1986.

City of Los Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency, 
Transportation System Management Rideshare Agreement for 
Downtown Los Angeles, June 21, 1986.

City of Richardson, Texas, Executive Summary of Robert 
Freilich and Martin Leitner on "Financing Transportation 
Improvements Through Impact Fees", Memorandum to Mayor 
and City Council from A. O'Rourke, "Transportation Impact 
Fee Program", Nov. 27, 1983.

City of Richardson, Texas, Draft Ordinance "Impact Fee 
for Transportation Management Improvements", Jan. 20, 
1986.


-163-

City of San Diego, "Facilities Benefits 
Assessments-Growth Management Implementation".

City of San Diego, Ordinance Relating to the Designation 
of Areas of Benefit to be Assessed to Coat of Public 
Facilities.  Ordinance 0-15318.

Marion Clawson, "why Not Sell Zoning and Rezoning? 
(legally, that is)," Cry California, Winter, 1966-67, pp. 
9, 39.

F. Jay Cummings, "State and Local Tax Bills: How Do 
Residents of Large Cities Fare?" Texas Business Review, 
Jan.-Feb., 1982, Vol. 56, No. 1, pp. 34-39.

Dallas Chamber of Commerce, Industrial Properties Guide, 
1986-87, Dallas, Texas, August, 1986.

Dallas Chamber of Commerce, Office Buildings Guide, 
Dallas, Texas, January, 1986.

Data Resources, Inc., Forecast of Revenues from The 
Dallas Area Rapid Transit Tax: State and Local Government 
Practice, May, 1986.

J.A.L. Dawson and I. Catling, "Electronic Road Pricing in 
Hong Kong", Transportation Research A, Vol. 20A, No. 2, 
March, 1986, 129-134.

James Duncan and Norman Standerfer, Impact Fees: The 
Changing Direction of Growth Management, Austin, Texas 
(?), November, 1985.

David J. Forkenbrock, "Highway Revenues and Expenditures: 
Some Emerging Policy Directions at the State Level", in 
Lester A. Hoel, Editor, Innovative Financing For 
Transportation: Practical Solutions and Experiences, U.S. 
Dept. of Transportation, Washington, D.C., April, 1986. 
(DOT-1-86-20).

David J. Forkenbrock and David J. Plazak, "Economic 
Development and State-Level Transportation Policy", 
Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40, No. 2, April, 1986,

Lawrence D. Goldstein, "A Local Share Financing Strategy 
for the Downtown Seattle Transportation Project", in 
Lester A. Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for 
Transportation, U.S. Dept. of Transportation, 1986, 
255-290.

Thomas J. Higgins, "Road Pricing Attempts in the United 
States", Transportation Research Vol. 20A, No. 2, March, 
1986. 145-150.

Lester A. Hoel, editor, Innovative Financing for 
Transportation: Practical Solutions and Experiences, 
Conference Proceedings, Prepared for Office of Technology 
and Planning Assistance, U.S. Dept. of Transportation, 
DOT-1-86-20, Washington, D.C., April, 1986.

William H. Inman, "Our Own Money Machine", Texas 
Business, March, 1985, 122-124.

International Bridge, Tunnel and Turnpike Association, 
Toll Rates Survey: U.S. and Canada Roads, Washington, 
D.C., July, 1985.

Renee Perkins Jaynes and Michael Levinson, "An Issue 
Paper on the Use of Public Improvement Districts in 
Dallas", City Manager' a Office, City of Dallas, January 
13, 1986.


-164-

Gary T. Johnson and Lester A. Hoel, University of 
Virginia, Charlottesville, Virginia 22901, An Inventory 
of Innovative Financing Techniques for Transportation, 
Prepared for University Research Program, Office of the 
Secretary of Transportation, DOT-1-86-08, Washington, 
D.C., April, 1986.

Gary T. Johnson and Lester A. Hoel, "Innovative Financing 
for Transportation: What are the Options?" in Lester A. 
Hoel, ed., Innovative Financing for  Transportation: 
Practical Solutions and Experiences, Office of U.S. 
Secretary of Transportation, Washington, D.C., April 
1986, DOT-1-86-20.

Knoxville-Knox County Metropolitan Planning Commission, 
Evaluation of Innovative Financing Techniques: Knoxville, 
Tennessee's Experience, Prepared for Office of Planning 
Assistance, Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D.C., June, 1984 (DOT-1-84-45).

Natalie McConnell-Fay "Tackling Traffic Congestion in the 
San Francisco Bay
Area", Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40. No. 2, April, 
1986, 159-170.

Lawrence J. Meisner, Kimley-Horn and Associates, Inc., 
Raleigh, North Carolina, Financing Urban Transportation 
Improvements, Report 2: The Use of Private Funds for 
Highway Improvements, Prepared for Federal Highway 
Administration, U.S. Department of Transportation, 
Washington, D.C., January, 1984 (DTFH61-82-C-00033).

Lennex L. Moak, Municipal Bonds: Planning, Sale & 
Administration, Chicago, Illinois: Municipal Finance 
Officers Association, 1982, 405 pp.

Steven A. Morrison, "A Survey of Road Pricing", 
Transportation Research A, Vol. 20A, No. 2, March, 1986, 
87-95; see 94-95 in particular, for a discussion of the 
Hong Kong pilot project.

Bahar Norris, "Road Utility Districts", Memorandum to 
Gordon A. Shunk, North
Central Texas Council of Governments, June 3, 1986.

Bahar Norris, "The Highway Commission's Updates on the 
Texas Transportation Corporation Act," Memorandum to 
Gordon A. Shunk, North Central Texas Council of 
Governments, June 3, 1986.

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Total 
Transportation Plan for the North Central Texas Region 
for 1990, Arlington, Texas, Oct., 1974.

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Population & 
Employment Projections by City, Arlington, Texas, July, 
1984.


North Central Texas Council of Governments, 1986 
Transportation Improvement Program for North Central 
Texas, Arlington, Texas, June, 1985.

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Current 
Housing 1986 Estimates, Arlington, Texas, March, 1986.

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Current 
Population 1986 Estimates, Arlington, Texas, May, 1986.

North Central Texas Council of Governments "Weekday VMT 
Summary Report, 1977-1985", Arlington, Texas, Revised May 
20, 1986.



-165-

North Central Texas Council of Governments, Mobility 
2000: The Regional Transportation Plan for North Central 
Texas, Arlington, Texas, May, 1986.

Orange County Transportation Commission, Findings: Toll 
Road Feasibility Stud Foothil1/Eastern Transportation 
Corridors, June, 1986.

Orange County Transportation Commission, SuperStreets 
Demonstration Project, 	March, 1986.

C. Kenneth Orski, "The Outlook For Urban Transportation", 
in Lester A. Hoel, Editor, Innovative Financing For 
Transportation: Practical Solutions and Experience, U.S. 
Department of Transportation, Washington, D.C., April 
1986, pp. 33-34. (DOT-1-86-20).

C. Kenneth Oraki, "Suburban Mobility: The Coming 
Transportation Crisis?" Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 
39, No. 2, April, 1985, 283-296.

John E. Peterson and Wesley C. Hough, Creative Capital 
Financing For State and Local Governments, Chicago, 
Illinois: Municipal Finance Officers Association, 1983, 
256 pp.

David L. Pugh, Christine Bailey Bishop, Charles W. 
Springer, Joanie Carson Raff, A Survey of Capital 
Recovery Fee Systems in Texas, Texas A & M University 
System, 1986.

Gary Reid and Donald Winkler, User Fees Among Cities in 
Los Angeles County and the Rest of Southern California, 
Loa Angeles: LA Taxpayers Association, 1986.

Rice Center, A Guide to Innovative Financing Mechanism 
For Mass Transportation, Prepared for Office of Planning 
Assistance, Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D.C., Dec., 1982 (DOT-1-82-53).

Rice Center, Alternative Financing for Urban 
Transportation: State-of-the-Art Case Analyses, Prepared 
for Federal Highway Administration and Urban Mass 
Transportation Administration, Washington, D.C., Oct., 
1983 (DOT-1-83-54).

Rice Center, Joint Center for Urban Mobility, Financing 
Urban Transportation Improvements, Report 3: A Guide to 
Alternative Financing Mechanisms for Urban Highways, 
Prepared for Federal Highway Administration, Urban Mass 
Transportation Administration, Washington, D.C., June, 
1984.

Rice Center, Houston, Texas, A Guide to Innovative 
Financing Mechanisms for Mass Transportation - An Update, 
Prepared for Urban Mass Transportation Administration, 
Washington, D.C., Dec., 1985.

Marc Samet, "Financing and Implementing Special 
Assessments", Dade County, Florida, 1984.

Robert C. Schaevitz, "Viability of Wide Area Assessment 
Districts for Financing Street Highway and Parking 
Improvements", in Lester A. Hoel, ed., Innovative 
Financing for Transportation, U.S. DOT, 1986, 173-196.

William E. Schmidt, New York Times Service, "Development 
Fees Harvest Cash and Protests", Austin 
American-Statesman, Nov. 4, 1985, E1.



-166-

Peter L. Shaw, "The Surface Transportation Assistance Act 
of 1982: Short-term Hopes and Long-Term Implications, 
"Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40, No. 3, July 1986, 
411-432.

Wilbur Smith and Associates, Dallas North Tollway and 
Proposed Extension, Phase I: Traffic and Revenues, 
Prepared for Texas Turnpike Authority, July, 1982.

Wilbur Smith and Associates, Dallas North Tollway and 
Extension, Phase I: Refinancing, Traffic and Revenues, 
October, 1985.

Southern California Rapid Transit District, "Benefit 
Assessment Report Metro Rail Benefit Assessment 
Districts.

SRI International, Reviewing Our Infrastructure-Workable 
Ways to Build and Maintain Public Facilities, Jan., 1983.

State of Texas, General & Special Laws, Vol. 1, 67th 
Legislature Regular Session 1981, chapter 1-506, pp. 
473-476.

State of Texas Comptroller of Public Accounts, Annual 
Report, Fiscal Year Ended 8/31/85, Austin, Texas, Nov. 4, 
1985.

State of Texas Comptroller of Public Accounts, "A Texas 
Lottery?", Fiscal Notes, May, 1986.
		
State of Texas Department of Highways and Public 
Transport, Annual Financial Report for Fiscal Year Ended Aug. 
31, 1985, unaudited, Austin, Texas, 1985.
		
State of Texas Department of Highways and Public 
Transportation, Texas Transportation Finance Facts, 1984, 
Austin, Texas, 1986.
	
State of Texas Legislative Budget Board, Texas State 
Services, Sixty-ninth Texas 	Legislature 1986-87, Austin, 
Texas, 1986.
	
State of Texas, Property Tax Board, Annual Report for Tax 
Year 1984, Austin, Texas, December, 1985.

State of Texas, Property Tax Code, Chapter 11, Section 11.25.

Texas Good Roads Transportation Association and Greater 
San Antonio Chamber of Commerce, Financing the Future: A 
Seminar Exploring Traditional and Innovative 
Transportation Funding Alternatives, San Antonio, Texas, 
Oct. 10, 1985.

Texas Turnpike Authority, Thirty Second Annual Report, 
1985, Dallas, Texas, March, 1986.

Texas Turnpike Authority, Dallas North Tollway, Financial 
Statements, Dallas, Texas, June 30, 1986.

Transportation Research Board, Transportation Research 
Record 900: State and Local Transportation Finance and 
Cost Allocation, Washington, D.C., 1983.


-167-

Transportation Research Board, Transportation Research 
Record 1009: Financing State and Local Transportation, 
Washington, D.C., 1985.

Transportation Research Board, National Research Council, 
Special Report 208, Proceedings of the Conference on 
Evaluating Alternative Local Transportation Financing 
Techniques, Denver, Colorado, November 28-30, 1984, 
Washington, D.C., 1985.

Urban Consortium, Inflation-Responsive Financing for 
Streets and Highways, DOT, 6/82, DOT-1-82-56.

U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 
Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism 1985-86 
Edition, Washington, D.C., 1986.
		
U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Toll Financing of U.S. 
Highways, Congress of the United States, December, 1985.
		
U.S. General Accounting Office, Highway Funding: Use of 
Toll revenues in
Financing Highway Projects, April 1986. GAO/RCED-86-130.
			
U.S. Federal Highway Administration, Highway Statistics 
1984, Washington, D.C.
			
U.S. Federal Highway Administration, State Highway Cost 
Allocation Guide, Volume II, Technical Appendix, 
Washington, D.C., Oct., 1984.
	
Erakine S. Walther, The Transportation Institute, North 
Carolina A&T State University, State and Local Financing 
of Public Transit Systems, Prepared for University 
Research and Training Program, Urban Mass Transportation 
Administration, U.S. Department of Transportation, 
(DOT-1-84-31), Washington, D.C., June, 1983.

Donald Winkler, Comparative Study of Business Taxation by 
Local Government in Southern California, (Los Angeles: LA 
Taxpayers Association, 1984).
			
Richard Wilson, Los Angeles Metro Rail Benefit 
Assessment: Analyzing Impacts
on Real Estate Economics, City of Los Angeles Community 
Redevelopment Agency, September, 1985.

Harold Wolman and George Reigeluth, The Urban Institute, 
Financing Urban Public Transportation: A Comparison of 
U.S. and Foreign Cities, Prepared for U.S.  Department of 
Transportation, Washington, D.C., April, 1980.
	
Arthur Young, Report of the Orange County Transportation 
Commission on a Service Authority For Freeway Emergencies 
(SAFE), Jan., 1986.

U.S. GOVERNMENT   PRINTING	   OFFICE:1987-181 - 763/40229




		This document is disseminated 
		under the sponsorship of the 
		Department of Transportation in 
		the interest of information 
		exchange.  The United States 
		Government assumes no liability 
		for its contents or use thereof.

		The United States Government does 
		not endorse manufacturers or 
		products. Trade names appear in 
		the document only because they are 
		essential to the content of the report.

		This report is being distributed 
		through the U.S. Department of 
		Transportation's Technology 
		Sharing Program.

		DOT-1-87-24


(fnc.html)
Jump To Top