Anarchy, State, and Rent Control (excerpted from _The New Republic_ Dec. 22 1986 pages 20-21) The underscore character indicates _italicized_ text. All emphasis and parenthetical comments are in the original. Postcard Cambridge: ANARCHY, STATE, AND RENT CONTROL Robert Nozick, a philosophy professor at Harvard, is the intellectual hero of libertarians. His book, _Anarchy, State, and Utopia_, winner of the National Book Award in 1974, argues that "free minds and free markets" are the key to a successful society. While endorsing personal choice on social issues like drugs and pornography, Nozick mocked the economic interventionism of contemporary liberals who, he said, are "willing to tolerate every kind of behavior except capitalistic acts between consenting adults." Alas, it now appears that like so many other advocates of the free market, Nozick is willing to make one small exception --himself. In September 1983, Nozick signed a one-year lease on a condominium apartment in Cambridge, Massachusetts, owned by Eric Segal, the eminent classical scholar and author of _Love Story_. Segal, who bought the place in 1972, has lived there only occasionally and now resides in England. The apartment is a beauty, actually two combined units with 2,500 square feet of space, a wine "safe", Jacuzzi, sauna, and a 50-foot balcony overlooking the Charles River. As a consenting adult, Nozick agreed to pay Segal $1,900 a month. When the lease came up for renewal a year later, Segal bumped the rent up to $2,400. A lot, but Cambridge is a hot real estate market and Nozick, as a consenting adult, signed again for another year. But he apparently was miffed. Cambridge, after all, has one of the nation's most draconic rent control ordinances --as do many college communities where students and junior professors have imposed economic regulations on the "townies" who rent them apartments during the school year. Was it possible, Nozick wondered, that Segal might be violating the law? Less than a month later, Nozick showed up at the offices of the Cambridge Rent Control Board and asked if the city rent regulation applied to his apartment. "We told him it certainly did," said Bernard "Buddy" Packer, who makes sure all rents are fair and square in Cambridge. "The final, legal, maximum rent on that apartment should have been $1,900." And so the matter was settled, as far as Buddy Packer and the Rent Control Board were concerned. Nozick's rent was rolled back to $1,900. He received a $500 refund on his first month's rent. But Nozick wasn't satisfied. Like the son of a missionary discovering pornography, Nozick apparently became fascinated with rent control. "I was up there showing the apartment to some brokers at one point," says Ken Edelman, a New York attorney who was soon representing Segal. "There was a copy of the Cambridge Rent Control Ordinance sitting on the coffee table." Nozick decided the situation was more grave than even the rent control board had suspected. In Cambridge, rent increases are allowed only through occasional citywide raises, or through individual exceptions granted to petitioning landlords. But how was the _original_ rent determined? The law says it is the rent at which the apartment was let when the ordinance first went into effect. Multifamily unit housing was regulated in 1970 and owner-occupied condominiums were brought under the law as of March 31, 1976. If an apartment was not being rented at the time, the first rent at which it was let becomes the base rent. All subsequent raises are figured by a complicated formula only the Cambridge Rent Control Board seems to understand. Nozick knew he had not been the first tenant. Segal had rented out the apartment several times before to friends and acquaintances. After some investigating, Nozick turned up a couple in the building who house-sat the apartment for six months in 1976, without a lease, paying only $675 a month. In September 1985, Nozick's second lease expired. Even though he had no contractual right to stay in Segal's apartment, he did not want to move out. The interventionist state to the rescue once again! Under Cambridge's rent control ordinance, even a tenant without a lease is evictable only if the owner himself wanted to move into the apartment. Not only did Nozick stay put, but a month later he filed suit against Segal in Cambridge District Court. Nozick argued the rent --based on the $675 base figure-- should now be only about $800. He demanded a $25,000 refund for two years of "overpayment" --plus triple damages. The case dragged on for two years. In May 1986 the Cambridge Rent Control Board issued a new ruling. Basing the rent on a 1977 lease where the tenant had paid $1,000, the board decided the final, legal, maximum rent should be $1,303. (Rent control boards always seem to choose mysterious figures in order to give themselves an air of authority. Segal's monthly maintenance, property tax, and mortgage costs were more than $2,000.) This fall the parties settled out of court. Nozick agreed to move out of the apartment on September 15, and Segal agreed to pay his tenant $31,000. "We thought it was a pretty good settlement," said Edelman, Segal's attorney. "Cambridge's rent control ordinance is one of the strictest in the country. Nozick was in a very strong position." Based on the $1,303 figure, however, the refund for the entire three-year "overcharge" should have been about $21,000. Why the extra $10,000? "Eric wants to sell the place," said Edelman. "With Nozick in there, the apartment was virtually unmarketable. Any new owner would inherit the problem. Basically, we had to pay off Nozick to get rid of him. Otherwise, he might have been there forever." Nozick refused all comment. No one, not even a philosopher, is morally obligated to live as if the world were the way he wishes it were. Robert Nozick pays taxes and is entitled to enjoy the government benefits they finance --even benefits he thinks should not exist. Perhaps the libertarian philosopher should not be expected to opt out of rent control voluntarily. But should he be pursuing his landlord through the maze of rent control regulations like a man possessed? And should he be using his ability to make a nuisance of himself under these regulations for simple, if lawful, cash extortion? They say that policeman make the best burglars. After a few years on the job, they know all the tricks. The same thing seems to be true of philosophers. If you're looking for someone to manipulate a rent control ordinance, find an advocate of the free market. William Tucker